The Level and Structure of Interest Rates

1 / 130
About This Presentation
Title:

The Level and Structure of Interest Rates

Description:

Over the last three decades interest rates have often followed patterns of ... are some investors who are risk loving, a risk loving market is an aberration, ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:92
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 131
Provided by: hpcus914

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: The Level and Structure of Interest Rates


1
Chapter 3
  • The Level and Structure of Interest Rates

2
Historical Interest Rate Patterns
  • Over the last three decades interest rates have
    often followed patterns of persistent increases
    or persistent decreases with fluctuations around
    these trends.
  • In the 1970s and early 1980s the U.S.s inflation
    led to increasing interest rates during that
    period. This period of increasing rates was
    particularly acute from the late 1970s through
    early 1980s when the U.S. Federal Reserve changed
    the direction of monetary policy by raising
    discount rates, increasing reserve requirements,
    and lowering monetary growth.

3
Historical Interest Rate Patterns
  • This period of increasing rates was followed by a
    period of declining rates from the early 1980s to
    the late 1980s, then a period of gradually
    increasing rates for most of the 1990s, and
    finally a period of decreasing rates from 2000
    through 2003.
  • The different interest rates levels observed
    since the 1970s can be explained by such factors
    as economic growth, monetary and fiscal policy,
    and inflation.

4
Historical Interest Rate Patterns
TREASURY BILL RATES, 1970-2003
5
Historical Interest Rate Spreads
  • In addition to the observed fluctuations in
    interest rate levels, there have also been
    observed spreads between the interest rates on
    bonds of different categories and terms to
    maturity over this same period.
  • For example, the spread between yields on Baa and
    AAA bonds is greater in the late 1980s and early
    1990s when the U.S. economy was in recession
    compared to the differences in the mid to late
    1990s when the U.S. economy was growing.
  • In general, spreads can be explained by
    differences in each bonds characteristics risk,
    liquidity, and taxability.

6
Historical Interest Rate Spreads
TREASURY BOND, Aaa CORPORATE, Baa CORPORATE, AND
MORTAGE RATES, 1970-2002
7
Historical Interest Rate Spreads
  • Interest rate differences can be observed between
    similar bonds with different maturities. The
    figures on the next slide shows two plots of the
    YTM on U.S. government bonds with different
    maturities for early 2002 and early 1981.
  • The graphs are known as yield curves and they
    illustrate what is referred to as the term
    structure of interest rates.
  • The lower graph shows a positively-sloped yield
    curve in early 2002 with rates on short-term
    government securities lower than
    intermediate-term and long-term ones.
  • In contrast, the upper graph shows a negatively
    sloped curve in early 1981 with short-term rates
    higher than intermediate- and long-term ones.

8
Historical Interest Rate SpreadsYield Curves
9
Objective
  • Understanding what determines both the overall
    level and structure of interest rates is an
    important subject in financial economics. Here,
    we examine the factors that are important in
    explaining the level and differences in interest
    rates.
  • Examining the behavior of overall interest rates
    using basic supply and demand analysis
  • Looking at how risk, liquidity, and taxes explain
    the differences in the rates on bonds of
    different categories.
  • Looking at four well-known theories that explain
    the term structure on interest rates.

10
Supply and Demand Analysis
  • One of the best ways to understand how market
    forces determine interest rates is to use
    fundamental supply and demand analysis.
  • In determining the supply and demand for bonds,
    let us treat different bonds as being alike and
    simply assume the bond in question is a
    one-period, zero-coupon bond paying a principal
    of F equal to 100 at maturity and priced at P0 to
    yield a rate i.
  • Given this type of bond, we want to determine the
    important factors that determine its supply and
    demand.

11
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Bond Demand Curve
  • Bond Demand Curve The curve shows an inverse
    relationship between, bond demand, BD, and its
    price, P0, and a direct relation between BD
    interest rate, i, given other factors are
    constant.
  • Bond demand curve is also called the supply of
    loanable funds curve.

12
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Bond Demand Curve
  • The factors held constant include the overall
    wealth or economic state of the economy, as
    measured by real output, gdp, the bonds risk
    relative to other assets, its liquidity relative
    to other assets, expected future interest rates,
    E(i) and inflation, and government policies

13
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Bond Demand Curve
  • Bond demand is inversely related to its price and
    directly related to interest rate.
  • The bond demand curve showing bond demand and
    price relation is negatively-sloped.
  • This reflects the fundamental assumption that
    investors will demand more bonds the lower the
    price or equivalently the greater the interest
    rate.
  • Changes in the economy, futures interest rate and
    inflation expectations, risk, liquidity, and
    government policies lead to either rightward or
    leftward shifts in the demand curve, reflecting
    greater or less bond demand at each price or
    interest rate.

14
  • Bond Demand Curve

15
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Bond Supply Curve
  • The bond supply curve shows the quantity supplied
    of bonds, BS, by corporations, governments, and
    intermediaries is directly related to the bonds
    price and inversely related interest rate, given
    other factors such as the state of the economy,
    government policy, and expected future inflation
    are constant
  • Bond supply curve is also called the demand of
    loanable funds curve.

16
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Bond Supply Curve
  • The bond supply curve is positively sloped.
  • The positively sloped curve reflects the
    fundamental assumption that corporations,
    governments, and financial intermediaries will
    sell more bonds the greater the bonds price or
    equivalently the lower the interest rate.
  • The bond supply curve will shift in response to
    changes in the state of the economy, government
    policy, and expected inflation.

17
  • Supply Curve for Bonds

18
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Equilibrium
  • The equilibrium rate, i and price, P0, are
    graphically defined by the intersection of the
    bond supply and bond demand curves.

19
  • Supply and Demand for Bonds

20
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Proof of Equilibrium
  • If the bond price were below this equilibrium
    price (or equivalently the interest rate were
    above the equilibrium rate), then investors would
    want more bonds than issuers were willing to
    sell.
  • This excess demand would drive the price of the
    bonds up, decreasing the demand and increasing
    the supply until the excess was eliminated.

21
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Proof of Equilibrium
  • If the price on bonds were higher than its
    equilibrium (or interest rates lower that the
    equilibrium rate), then bondholders would want
    fewer bonds, while issuers would want to sell
    more bonds.
  • This excess supply in the market would lead to
    lower prices and higher interest rates,
    increasing bond demand and reducing bond supply
    until the excess supply was eliminated.

22
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
23
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
24
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
25
Bond Demand and Supply Analysis
26
Cases Using Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Expansionary Open Market Operation
  • Central Bank buys bonds, decreasing the bond
    supply and shifting the bond supply curve to the
    left.
  • The impact would be an increase in bond prices
    and a decrease in interest rates. Intuitively, as
    the central bank buys bonds, they will push the
    price of bond up and interest rate down.

27
Expansionary Open Market Operation
28
Cases Using Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Economic Recession
  • In an economic recession, there is less capital
    formation and therefore fewer bonds are sold.
  • This leads to a decrease in bond supply and a
    leftward shift in the bond supply curve.
  • The recession also lowers bond demand, shifting
    the bond demand curve to the left.
  • If the supply effect dominates the demand effect,
    then there will be an increase in bond prices and
    a decrease in interest rates.

29
Economic Recession
30
Cases Using Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Treasury Financing of a Deficit
  • With a government deficit, the Treasury will have
    to sell more bonds to finance the shortfall.
  • Their sale of bonds will increase the supply of
    bonds, shifting the bond supply curve to the
    right, initially creating an excess supply of
    bonds.
  • This excess supply will force bond prices down
    and interest rates up.

31
Treasury Financing of Deficit
32
Cases Using Demand and Supply Analysis
  • Economic Expansion
  • In a period of economic expansion, there is an
    increase in capital formation and therefore more
    bonds are being sold to finance the capital
    expansion.
  • This leads to an increase in bond supply and a
    rightward shift in the bond supply curve.
  • The expansion also increases bond demand,
    shifting the bond demand curve to the right.
  • If the supply effect dominates the demand
    effects, then there will be a decrease in bond
    prices and an increase in interest rates.

33
Economic Expansion
34
Risk and Risk Premium
  • Investment risk is the uncertainty that the
    actual rate of return realized from a security
    will differ from the expected rate.
  • In general, a riskier bond will trade in the
    market at a price that yields a greater YTM than
    a less risky bond.
  • The difference in the YTM of a risky bond and the
    YTM of less risky or risk-free bond is referred
    to as a risk spread or risk premium.

35
Risk and Risk Premium
  • The risk premium, RP, indicates how much
    additional return investors must earn in order to
    induce them to buy the riskier bond
  • We can use the supply and demand model to show
    how the risk premium is positive.

RP YTM on Risky Bond - YTM on Risk-Free Bond
36
Risk and Risk Premium
  • Consider the equilibrium adjustment that would
    occur for two identical bonds (C and T) that are
    priced with the same yields, but events occur
    that make one of the bonds more risky.

37
Risk and Risk Premium
  • The increased riskiness on the one bond (Bond C)
    would cause its demand to decrease, shifting its
    bond demand curve to the left. That bonds
    riskiness would also make the other bond (Bond T)
    more attractive, increasing its demand and
    shifting its demand curve to the right.
  • At the new equilibriums, the riskier bonds price
    is lower and its rate greater than the other.
  • The different risk associated with bonds leads to
    a market adjustment in which at the new
    equilibrium there is a positive risk premium.

38
Risk Premium
The riskiness of Bond C increases the demand for
Bond T, shifting its bond demand curve to the
right. Impact A Lower Interest Rate on Bond T
The riskiness of Bond C decreases its demand,
shifting its bond demand curve to the left.
Impact A Higher Interest Rate on Bond C
39
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • The size of the risk premium depends on
    investors attitudes toward risk.
  • To see this relation, suppose there are only two
    bonds available in the market a risk-free bond
    and a risky bond.

40
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • Suppose the risk-free bond is a zero-coupon bond
    promising to pay 1,000 at the end of one year
    and currently is trading for 909.09 to yield a
    one-year risk-free rate, Rf, of 10

41
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • Suppose the risky bond is a one-year zero coupon
    bond with a principal of 1,000.
  • Suppose there is a .8 probability the bond would
    pay its principal of 1,000 and a .2 probability
    it would pay nothing.
  • The expected dollar return from the risky bond is
    therefore 800

E(Return) .8(1,000) .2(0) 800
42
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • Given the choice of two securities, suppose that
    the market were characterized by investors who
    were willing to pay 727.27 for the risky bond,
    in turn yielding them an expected rate of return
    of 10
  • In this case, investors would be willing to
    receive an expected return from the risky
    investment that is equal to the risk-free rate of
    10, and the risk premium, E(R) - Rf, would be
    equal to zero.
  • In finance terminology, such a market is
    described as risk neutral.

RP 0 ? Risk-Neutral Market
43
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • Instead of paying 727.27, suppose investors like
    the chance of obtaining returns greater than 10
    (even though there is a chance of losing their
    investment), and as a result are willing to pay
    750 for the risky bond. In this case, the
    expected return on the bond would be 6.67 and
    the risk premium would be negative
  • By definition, markets in which the risk premium
    is negative are called risk loving.

RP lt 0 ? Risk-Loving Market
44
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • Risk loving markets can be described as ones in
    which investors enjoy the excitement of the
    gamble and are willing to pay for it by accepting
    an expected return from the risky investment that
    is less than the risk-free rate.
  • Even though there are some investors who are risk
    loving, a risk loving market is an aberration,
    with the exceptions being casinos, sports
    gambling markets, lotteries, and racetracks.

45
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • Suppose most of the investors making up our
    market were unwilling to pay 727.27 or more for
    the risky bond.
  • In this case, if the price of the risky bond were
    727.27 and the price of the risk-free were
    909.09, then there would be little demand for
    the risky bond and a high demand for the
    risk-free one.
  • Holders of the risky bonds who wanted to sell
    would therefore have to lower their price,
    increasing the expected return. On the other
    hand, the high demand for the risk-free bond
    would tend to increase its price and lower its
    rate.

46
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • Suppose the markets cleared when the price of the
    risky bond dropped to 701.75 to yield 14, and
    the price of the risk-free bond increased to
    917.43 to yield 9
  • In this case, the risk premium would be 5

47
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • By definition, markets in which the risk premium
    is positive are called risk-averse markets.
  • In a risk-averse market, investors require
    compensation in the form of a positive risk
    premium to pay them for the risk they are
    assuming.
  • Risk-averse investors view risk as a disutility,
    not a utility as risk-loving investors do.

RP gt 0 ? Risk-Averse Market
48
Risk Premiums and Investors Return-Risk Premiums
  • Historically, security markets such as the stock
    and corporate bond markets have generated rates
    of return that, on average, have exceeded the
    rates on Treasury securities.
  • This would suggest that such markets are risk
    averse.
  • Since most markets are risk averse, a relevant
    question is the degree of risk aversion.
  • The degree of risk aversion can be measured in
    terms of the size of the risk premium. The
    greater investors risk aversion, the greater the
    demand for risk-free securities and the lower the
    demand for risky ones, and thus the larger the
    risk premium.

49
Liquidity and Liquidity Premium
  • Liquid securities are those that can be easily
    traded and in the short-run are absent of risk.
  • In general, we can say that a less liquid bond
    will trade in the market at a price that yields a
    greater YTM than a more liquid one.

50
Liquidity and Liquidity Premium
  • The difference in the YTM of a less liquid bond
    and the YTM of a more liquid one is defined as
    the liquidity premium, LP

LP YTM on Less Liquid Bond - YTM on
More-Liquid Bond
51
Liquidity and Liquidity Premium
  • Consider the equilibrium adjustment that would
    occur for two identical bonds that are priced
    with the same yields, but events occur that make
    one of the bonds less liquid.
  • The decrease in liquidity on one of the bonds
    would cause its demand to decrease, shifting its
    bond demand curve to the left. The decrease in
    that bonds liquidity would also make the other
    bond relatively more liquid, increasing its
    demand and shifting its demand curve to the
    right.
  • Once the markets adjust to the liquidity
    difference between the bonds, then the less
    liquid bonds price would be lower and its yield
    greater than the relative more liquid bond.
  • Thus, the difference in liquidity between the
    bonds leads to a market adjustment in which there
    is a difference between rates due to their
    different liquidity features.

52
Liquidity Premium
The decrease in liquidity of Bond C increases
the demand for Bond T, shifting its bond demand
curve to the right. Impact A Lower Interest
Rate on Bond T
The decrease in liquidity of Bond C decreases
its demand, shifting its bond demand curve to
the left. Impact A Higher Interest Rate on Bond
C
53
Taxability
  • An investor in a 40 income tax bracket who
    purchased a fully-taxable 10 corporate bond at
    par, would earn an after-tax yield, ATY, of 6
    ATY 10(1-.4).
  • In general, the ATY can be found by solving for
    that yield, ATY, that equates the bonds price to
    the present value of its after-tax cash flows

54
Taxability and Pre-Tax Yield Spread
  • Bonds that have different tax treatments but
    otherwise are identical will trade at different
    pre-tax YTM.
  • That is, the investor in the 40 tax bracket
    would be indifferent between the 10
    fully-taxable corporate bond and a 6 tax-exempt
    municipal bond selling at par, if the two bond
    were identical in all other respects.
  • The two bonds would therefore trade at equivalent
    after-tax yields of 6, but with a pre-tax yield
    spread of 4

55
Taxability and Pre-Tax Yield Spread
  • In general, bonds whose cash flows are subject to
    less taxes trade at a lower YTM than bonds that
    are subject to more taxes.
  • Historically, taxability explains why U.S.
    municipal bonds whose coupon interest is exempt
    from federal income taxes, have traded at yields
    below default-free U.S. Treasury securities even
    though many municipals are subject to default
    risk.

56
Term Structure of Interest Rates
  • Term Structure examines the relationship between
    YTM and maturity, M.
  • Yield Curve Plot of YTM against M for bonds that
    are otherwise alike.

57
Term Structure of Interest Rates
  • A yield curve can be constructed from current
    observations. For example, one could take all
    outstanding corporate bonds from a group in which
    the bonds are almost identical in all respects
    except their maturities, then generate the
    current yield curve.
  • For investors who are more interested in long-run
    average yields instead of current ones, the yield
    curve could be generated by taking the average
    yields over a sample period (e.g., 5-year
    averages) and plotting these averages against
    their maturities.
  • Finally, a widely-used approach is to generate a
    spot yield curve from spot rates.

58
Term Structure of Interest Rates
  • Shapes Yield curves have tended to take on one
    of the three shapes
  • They can be positively-sloped with long-term
    rates being greater than shorter-term ones.
  • Such yield curves are called normal or upward
    sloping curves. They are usually convex from
    below, with the YTM flattening out at higher
    maturities.
  • Yield curves can also be negatively-sloped, with
    short-term rates greater than long-term ones.
  • These curves are known as inverted or downward
    sloping yield curves. Like normal curves, these
    curves also tend to be convex, with the yields
    flattening out at the higher maturities.
  • Yield curves can be relatively flat, with YTM
    being invariant to maturity.

59
Term Structure of Interest Rates
60
Theories of the Term Structure of Interest Rates
  • The actual shape of the yield curve depends on
  • The types of bonds under consideration (e.g., AAA
    bond versus B bond)
  • Economic conditions (e.g., economic growth or
    recession, tight monetary conditions, etc.)
  • The maturity preferences of investors and
    borrowers
  • Investors' and borrowers' expectations about
    future rates, inflation, and the state of
    economy.

61
Theories of the Term Structure of Interest Rates
  • Four theories have evolved over the years to try
    to explain the shapes of yield curves
  • Market Segmentation Theory (MST)
  • Preferred Habitat Theory (PHT)
  • Liquidity Premium Theory (LPT)
  • Pure Expectation Theory (PET)

62
Market Segmentation Theory
  • MST Yield curve is determined by supply and
    demand conditions unique to each maturity
    segment.
  • MST assumes that markets are segmented by
    maturity.

63
Market Segmentation Theory
  • Example The yield curve for high quality
    corporate bonds could be segmented into two
    markets
  • short-term
  • long-term

64
Market Segmentation Theory
  • Short-Term Market
  • The supply of short-term corporate bonds, such as
    commercial paper would depend on business demand
    for short-term assets such as inventories,
    accounts receivables, and the like
  • The demand for short-term corporate bonds would
    emanate from investors looking to invest their
    excess cash for short periods.
  • The demand for short-term bonds by investors and
    the supply of such bonds by corporations would
    ultimately determine the rate on short-term
    corporate bonds.

65
Market Segmentation Theory
  • Long-Term Market
  • The supply of long-term bonds would come from
    corporations trying to finance their long-term
    assets (plant expansion, equipment purchases,
    acquisitions, etc.).
  • The demand for such bonds would come from
    investors, either directly or indirectly through
    institutions (e.g., pension funds, mutual funds,
    insurance companies, etc.), who have long-term
    liabilities and horizon dates.
  • The demand for long-term bonds by investors and
    the supply of such bonds by corporations would
    ultimately determine the rate on long-term
    corporate bonds.

66
Market Segmentation Theory Illustration
  • Short-Term Market

Yield Curve for corporate bonds with two maturity
segments ST and LT
67
Market Segmentation Theory Illustration
  • Long-Term Market

68
Market Segmentation Theory
  • Important to MST is the idea of unique or
    independent markets.
  • According to MST, the short-term bond market is
    unaffected by rates determined in the
    intermediate or long-term markets, and vice
    versa.
  • This independence assumption is based on the
    premise that investors and borrowers have a
    strong need to match the maturities of their
    assets and liabilities.

69
MST Supply and Demand Model
  • One way to examine how market forces determine
    the shape of yield curves is to examine MST using
    our supply and demand analysis.
  • Consider a simple world in which there are two
    types of corporate and government treasury bonds
  • Corporate bonds long-term (BcLT) and short-term
    (BcST)
  • Treasury bonds long-term (BTLT) and short-term
    (BTLT).
  • Assumptions The supplies and demands for each
    sector and segment are based on the following
    assumptions

70
MST Supply and Demand Model
  • Assumption 1 Short-Term Bond Demand for
    Corporate and Treasury
  • The most important factors determining the demand
    for short-term bonds (both corporate and
    Treasury) are the bonds own price or interest
    rate, government policy, liquidity, and risk.
  • Short-term bond demand is assumed to be inversely
    related to its price and directly related to its
    own rate (negatively sloped bond demand curves)
    government actions that affect the supply of
    loanable funds also can change bond demand (e.g.,
    monetary policy changing bank reserve
    requirements).
  • The demand for the short-term bond in one sector
    is also assumed to be an inverse function of the
    short-term rate in the other sector, but not the
    long-term rate in either its sector or the other
    sector given the assumption of segmented markets.

71
MST Supply and Demand Model
  • Assumption 1 Short-Term Bond Demand for
    Corporate and Treasury

72
MST Supply and Demand Model
  • Assumption 2 Long-Term Bond Demand for
    Corporate and Treasury
  • The most important factors determining the demand
    for long-term bonds (both corporate and Treasury)
    are the bonds own price or interest rate,
    government policy such as monetary actions (e.g.,
    change in bank reserve requirements), liquidity,
    and risk.
  • Demand is assumed to be inversely related to its
    own price and directly related to its own rate
    (negatively sloped bond demand curves).
  • In addition, the demand for the long-term bond in
    one sector is an inverse function of the
    long-term rate in the other sector, but not a
    function of short-term rates given the market
    segmentation assumption.

73
MST Supply and Demand Model
  • Assumption 2 Long-Term Bond Demand for Corporate
    and Treasury

74
MST Supply and Demand Model
  • Assumption 3 Long-Term and Short-Term Bond
    Supplies for Corporate
  • The supplies of short-term and long-term
    corporate bonds are directly related to their own
    prices and inversely to their own interest rates
    (positively sloped corporate bond supply curve)
    and directly related to general economic
    conditions, increasing in economic expansion and
    decreasing in recession.

75
MST Supply and Demand Model
  • Assumption 4 Long-Term and Short-Term Bond
    Supplies for Treasury
  • The supplies of Treasury bonds depend only on
    government actions (monetary and fiscal policy),
    and not on the economic state or interest rates.
  • This assumption says that the sale or purchase of
    Treasury securities by the central bank or the
    Treasury is a policy decision. The assumption
    that the supply of Treasury securities depends on
    government actions and not interest rates means
    that the bond supply curve is vertical.

76
MST Supply and Demand Model
  • In the exhibit, the two equilibrium rates for
    short-term and long-term corporate bonds are
    plotted against their corresponding maturities to
    generate the yield curve for corporate bonds.
  • Similarly, the equilibrium rates for short-term
    and long-term Treasury bonds are plotted against
    their corresponding maturities to generate the
    yield curve for Treasury bonds.

77
Market Segmentation Theory Model
78
MST Supply and Demand Model
  • These yield curves, in turn, capture an MST world
    in which interest rates for each segment are
    determined by the supply and demand for that
    bond, with the rates on bonds in the other
    maturity segments having no effect.
  • In general, the positions and the shapes of the
    yield curves depend on the factors that determine
    the supply and demand for short-term and
    long-term bonds.

79
MST Cases Using SD Model
  • Economic Expansion
  • When an economy moves into a period of economic
    growth, business demand for short-term and
    long-term assets increases.
  • As a result, many companies issue more short-term
    bonds to finance their larger inventories and
    accounts receivables. They also issue more
    long-term bonds to finance their increase in
    investments in plants, equipment, and other
    long-term assets.
  • In the bond market, these actions cause the
    short-term and the long-term supplies of bonds to
    increase as the economy grows.

80
MST Cases Using SD Model
  • Economic Expansion
  • At the initial interest rates, the increase in
    bonds outstanding creates an excess supply. This
    drives bond prices down and the YTM up.
  • Using the supply and demand model, the economic
    expansion shifts the corporate short-term and
    long-term bond supply curves to the right,
    creating an excess supply for short-term bonds at
    icST and an excess supply for long-term bonds at
    icLT.
  • The excess causes corporate bond prices to fall
    and rates to rise until a new equilibrium is
    reached (icST and icLT).

81
MST Cases Using SD Model
  • Economic Expansion
  • As the rates on short-term and long-term
    corporate bonds increase, short-term and
    long-term Treasury securities become relatively
    less attractive.
  • As a result, the demands for short-term and
    long-term Treasuries decrease, shifting the
    short-term and long-term Treasury bond demand
    curves to the left and creating an excess supply
    in both Treasury markets at their initial rates.
  • Like the corporate bond markets, the excess
    supply in the Treasury security markets will
    cause their prices to decrease and their rates to
    rise until a new equilibrium is attained.

82
MST Cases Using SD Model
  • Economic Expansion
  • Thus, the supply and demand analysis shows that a
    recession has a tendency to increase both
    short-term and long-term rates for corporate
    bonds, and by a substitution effect, increase
    short-term and long-term Treasury rates.
  • Hence, an economic expansion causes the yield
    curves for both sectors to shift up.

83
Economic Expansion
84
MST Cases Using SD Model
  • Government surplus in which the Treasury buys
    existing long-term Treasury bonds
  • When the Treasury uses a surplus to buy long-term
    Treasury securities there is a decrease in the
    supply of long-term Treasuries (leftward shift in
    the Treasury LT bond supply curve).
  • The decrease in supply would push the price of
    the long-term government securities up, resulting
    in a lower long-term Treasury yield.

85
MST Cases Using SD Model
  • Government surplus in which the Treasury buys
    existing long-term Treasury bonds
  • In the corporate bond market, the lower rates on
    long-term government securities would lead to an
    increase in the demand for long-term corporate
    securities (rightward shift in the corporate LT
    bond demand curve), which, in turn, would lead to
    an excess demand in that market.
  • As bondholders try to buy long-term corporate
    bonds, the prices on such bonds would increase,
    causing the yields on long-term corporate bonds
    to fall until a new equilibrium is reached.

86
MST Cases Using SD Model
  • Government surplus in which the Treasury buys
    existing long-term Treasury bonds
  • Thus, the purchase of the long-term Treasury
    securities decreases both long-term government
    and long-term corporate rates.
  • Since the long-term market is assumed to be
    independent of short-term rates, the total
    adjustment to the Treasurys purchase of
    long-term securities would occur through the
    decrease in long-term corporate and Treasury
    rates.
  • If corporate and Treasury yield curves were
    initially flat, the Treasurys action would cause
    the yield curves to become negatively sloped.

87
Government surplus in which the
Treasury buys existing long-term Treasury bonds
88
MST Cases Using SD Model
  • Contractionary open market operation in which
    the Central Bank sells some of it short-term
    Treasury securities
  • A contractionary OMO in which the Fed sells
    short-term Treasury securities would cause the
    price on short-term Treasury securities to
    decrease and their yield to increase. This would
    be reflected by a rightward shift in the
    short-term Treasury bond supply curve, as the
    Central Bank sells it securities to the public.
  • As the yield on short-term Treasuries increases,
    the demand for short-term corporate would
    decrease (demand curve shifting left), leading to
    lower prices and higher yields on short-term
    corporate bonds.

89
MST Cases Using SD Model
  • Contractionary open market operation in which
    the Central Bank sells some of it short-term
    Treasury securities
  • Since the long-term market is assumed to be
    independent of short-term rates, the total
    adjustment to the Central banks sale of
    short-term securities to the public would be in
    the short-term corporate and Treasury markets
    with no impact on the long-term markets.
  • If both the Treasury and corporate yield curves
    were initially flat, then the contractionary OMO
    would result in new negatively sloped yield
    curves.

90
Contractionary Open Market
Operation Central Bank sells short-term
Treasuries
91
MST Outline of Cases Using SD Model
  • Recession
  • Outline Decrease in capital formation (S-T and
    L-T) ? Fewer bonds sold (S-T and L-T) ? Excess
    demand for bonds (S-T and L-T) ? Bond prices
    increase and rates decrease. ? Downward shift in
    YC

92
MST Outline of Cases Using SD Model
  • Expansionary open market operation in which the
    central bank buys short-term Treasury securities
  • Outline Central bank buys S-T Treasuries
    (T-bills) ? T-bill prices increase and rates
    decrease ? Substitution effect in which the
    demand for S-T corporate securities increase,
    causing their prices to increase and their yields
    to decrease. ? Tendency for YC to become
    positively sloped.

93
MST Outline of Cases Using SD Model
  • Treasury Sale of long-term Treasury bonds
  • Outline Treasury sells L-T Treasuries (T-Bonds)
    ? T-Bond prices decrease and yields increase ?
    Substitution effect in which the demand for L-T
    corporate securities decrease, causing their
    prices to decrease and their rates to increase. ?
    Tendency for YC to become positively sloped.

94
Preferred Habitat Theory (PHT)
  • PHT assumes that investors and borrowers are
    willing to give up their desired maturity segment
    and assume market risk if rates are attractive.
  • PHT asserts that investors and borrowers will be
    induced to forego their perfect hedges and shift
    out of their preferred maturity segments when
    supply and demand conditions in different
    maturity markets do not match.

95
Preferred Habitat Theory (PHT)
  • PHT is a necessary extension of the MST
  • If an economy is poorly hedged (e.g., more
    investors want ST investments and more borrowers
    want to borrow LT), then the market will not be
    in equilibrium.
  • In such cases, ST and LT rates will change and
    the markets will clear as investors and borrowers
    give up their hedge.

96
Preferred Habitat Theory (PHT)
  • To illustrate PHT, consider an economic world in
    which, on the demand side, investors in corporate
    securities, on average, prefer short-term to
    long-term instruments, while on the supply side,
    corporations have a greater need to finance
    long-term assets than short-term, and therefore
    prefer to issue more long-term bonds than
    short-term.
  • Combined, these relative preferences would cause
    an excess demand for short-term bonds and an
    excess supply for long-term claims and an
    equilibrium adjustment would have to occur.

97
Preferred Habitat Theory (PHT)
  • In the long-term market, the excess supply would
    force issuers to lower their bond prices, thus
    increasing bond yields and inducing some
    investors to change their short-term investment
    demands.
  • In the short-term market, the excess demand would
    cause bond prices to increase and rates to fall,
    inducing some corporations to finance their
    long-term assets by selling short-term claims.
  • Ultimately, equilibriums in both markets would be
    reached with long-term rates higher than
    short-term rates, a premium necessary to
    compensate investors and borrowers/issuers for
    the market risk they've assumed.

98
Preferred Habitat Theory
  • Poorly Hedged Economy Investors, on average,
    prefer ST investments corporate borrowers, on
    average, prefer to borrow LT (sell LT corporate
    bonds)

99
Liquidity Preference Theory
  • Long-term bonds are more price sensitive to
    interest rate changes than short-term bonds. As
    a result, the prices of long-term securities tend
    to be more volatile and therefore more risky than
    short-term securities.
  • The Liquidity Premium Theory (LPT), also referred
    to as the Risk Premium Theory (RPT), posits that
    there is a liquidity premium for long-term bonds
    over short-term bonds.

100
Liquidity Preference Theory
  • According to LPT, if investors were risk averse,
    then they would require some additional return
    (liquidity premium, LP) in order to hold
    long-term bonds instead of short-term ones.

101
Liquidity Preference Theory
  • Thus, if the yield curve were initially flat, but
    had no risk premium factored in to compensate
    investors for the additional volatility they
    assumed from buying long-term bonds, then the
    demand for long-term bonds would decrease and
    their rates increase until risk-averse investors
    were compensated.
  • In this case, the yield curve would become
    positively sloped.

102
Pure Expectations Theory
  • Expectation theories address the question of what
    impact expectations have on the current yield
    curve.
  • One of these theories is the Pure Expectations
    Theory (PET) also referred to as the unbiased
    expectations theory (UET).
  • PET posits that the yield curve is governed by
    the condition that the implied forward rate is
    equal to the expected sport rate.

103
Pure Expectations Theory
  • To illustrate PET
  • Consider a market consisting of only two bonds a
    risk-free one-year zero-coupon bond and a
    risk-free two-year zero-coupon bond, both with
    principals of 100.
  • Suppose that supply and demand conditions are
    such that both the one-year and two-year bonds
    are trading at an 8 YTM.
  • Suppose that the market expects the yield curve
    to shift up to 10 next year, but, as yet, has
    not factored that expectation into its current
    investment decisions.
  • Finally, assume the market is risk-neutral, such
    that investors do not require a risk premium for
    investing in risky securities (i.e., they will
    accept an expected rate on a risky investment
    that is equal to the risk-free rate).

104
Pure Expectations Theory
  • Question
  • What is the impact of the expectation on the
    current yield curve?

105
Pure Expectations Theory
  • Consider investors with HD 2 years
  • Alternatives
  • Buy 2-year bond at 8
  • Buy a series of 1-year bonds 1-year bond today
    at 8 and 1-year bond one year later at E(r11)
    10. The expected return from
    the series would be 9
  • In a risk-neutral world, investors with HD 2
    years would prefer the series of 1-year bonds
    over the 2-year bond.

106
Pure Expectations Theory
  • Consider investors with HD 1 year.
  • Alternatives
  • Buy 1-year bond at 8.
  • Buy a 2-year bonds at 8 for P2 100/(1.08)2
    85.734, then sell it one year later at an
    expected price of E(P11) 100/(1.10) 90.91.
    The expected rate of return would be 6
  • In a risk-neutral world, investors with HD 1
    year would prefer the 1-year bond over the 2-year
    bond.

107
Pure Expectations Theory
  • Thus, in a risk-neutral market with an
    expectation of higher rates next year, both
    investors with one-year horizon dates and
    investors with two-year horizon dates would
    purchase one-year instead of two-year bonds
  • If enough investors do this, an increase in the
    demand for one-year bonds and a decrease in the
    demand for two-year bonds would occur until the
    average annual rate on the two-year bond is equal
    to the equivalent annual rate from the series of
    one-year investments (or the one-year bond's rate
    is equal to the rate expected on the two-year
    bond held one year).

108
Pure Expectations Theory
  • Investors with HD of 2 years and those with HD of
    1 year would prefer one-year bonds over two- year
    bonds.
  • Market Response

109
Pure Expectations Theory
  • In the example, if the price on a two-year bond
    fell such that it traded at a YTM of 9 and the
    rate on a one-year bond stayed at 8, then
    investors with two-year horizon dates would be
    indifferent between a two-year bond yielding a
    certain 9 and a series of one-year bonds
    yielding 10 and 8, for an expected rate of 9.
  • Investors with one-year horizon dates would
    likewise be indifferent between a one-year bond
    yielding 8 and a two-year bond purchased at 9
    and sold one year later at 10, for an expected
    one-year rate of 8.

110
Pure Expectations Theory
  • Thus in this case, the impact of the market's
    expectation of higher rates would be to push
    2-year rates up to 9.
  • Note With YTM2 9 and YTM1 8, the implied
    forward rate is f11 10 -- the same rate as the
    expected rate E(r11).

111
Pure Expectations Theory
  • Assume that the market response is one in which
    only the demand for 2-year bonds is affected by
    the expectations.

112
Pure Expectations Theory
  • In the above example, the yield curve is
    positively sloped, reflecting expectations of
    higher rates.
  • By contrast, if the yield curve were currently
    flat at 10 and there was a market expectation
    that it would shift down to 8 next year, then
    the expectation of lower rates would cause the
    yield curve to become negatively sloped.

113
Pure Expectations Theory
  • That is, given a yield curve currently flat at
    10 and a market expectation that it would shift
    down to 8 next year, an investor with a two-year
    horizon date would prefer the two-year bond at
    10 to a series of one-year bonds yielding an
    expected rate of only 9 (E(R)
    (1.10)(1.08)1/2 -1 .09).
  • Similarly, an investor with a one-year horizon
    would also prefer buying a two-year bond that has
    an expected rate of return of 12 (P2
    100/(1.10)2 82.6446, E(P11) 100/1.08
    92.5926, E(R) 92.5926-82.6446/82.6446
    .12) to the one-year bond that yields only 10.

114
Pure Expectations Theory
  • In markets for both one-year and two-year bonds,
    the expectations of lower rates would cause the
    demand and price of the two-year bond to
    increase, lowering its rate, and the demand and
    price for the one-year bond to decrease,
    increasing its rate.

115
Pure Expectations Theory
Market expects the yield curve to shift down
from 10 to 8.
Investor with a one-year horizon would prefer
buying a two-year bond that has an expected rate
of return of 12 to the one-year bond that
yields only 10 P2 100/(1.10)2 82.6446
E(P11) 100/1.08 92.5926 E(R)
92.5926-82.6446/82.6446 .12
Investors with two-year horizon dates would
prefer the two-year bond at 10 to a series of
one-year bonds yielding an expected rate of only
9 (E(R) (1.10)(1.08)1/2 -1 .09)
YC become negatively sloped
116
Pure Expectations Theory
  • The adjustments would continue until the rate on
    the two-year bond equaled the average rate from
    the series of one-year investments, or until the
    rate on the one-year bond equaled the expected
    rate from holding a two-year bond one year (or
    when the implied forward rate is equal to
    expected spot rates).
  • In this case, if one-year rates stayed at 8,
    then the demand for the two-year bond would
    increase until it was priced to yield 9 - the
    expected rate from the series (1.10)(1.08)1/2
    -1 .09

117
Pure Expectations Theory
  • Assume that the market response is one in which
    only the demand for 2-year bonds is affected by
    the expectations.

118
Features of PET
  • One of the features of the PET is that in
    equilibrium the yield curve reflects current
    expectations about future rates. From our
    preceding examples
  • When the equilibrium yield curve was positively
    sloped, the market expected higher rates in the
    future
  • When the curve was negatively sloped, the market
    expected lower rates.

119
Features of PET
  • 2. PET intuitively captures what should be
    considered as normal market behavior.
  • For example, if long-term rates were expected to
    be higher in the future, long-term investors
    would not want to purchase long-term bonds now,
    given that next period they would be expecting
    higher yields and lower prices on such bonds.
    Instead, such investors would invest in
    short-term securities now, reinvesting later at
    the expected higher long-term rates.
  • In contrast, borrowers/issuers wishing to borrow
    long-term would want to sell long-term bonds now
    instead of later at possibly higher rates.
  • Combined, the decrease in demand for long-term
    bonds by investors and the increase in the supply
    of long-term bonds by borrowers would serve to
    lower long-term bond prices and increase yields,
    leading to a positively-sloped yield curve.

120
Features of PET
  • 3. If PET strictly holds (i.e., we can accept all
    of the model's assumptions), then the expected
    future rates would be equal to the implied
    forward rates. As a result, one could forecast
    futures rates and future yield curves by simply
    calculating implied forward rates from current
    rates.

121
Features of PET
  • The last feature suggests that given a spot yield
    curve, one could use PET to estimate next
    period's spot yield curve by determining the
    implied forward rates.
  • The exhibit on the next slide shows spot rates on
    bonds with maturities ranging from one year to
    five years (Column 2). From these rates,
    expected spot rates (St) are generated for bonds
    one year from the present (Column 3) and two
    years from the present (Column 4). The expected
    spot rates shown are equal to their corresponding
    implied forward rates.

122
Features of PET
123
Features of PET
124
Features of PET
  • According to PET, if the market is risk-neutral,
    then the implied forward rate is equal to the
    expected spot rate, and in equilibrium, the
    expected rate of return for holding any bond for
    one year would be equal to the current spot rate
    on one-year bonds.

125
Features of PET
  • For example, the expected rate of return from
    purchasing a two-year zero-coupon bond at the
    spot rate of 10.5 and selling it one year later
    at an expected one-year spot rate equal to the
    implied forward rate of f11 11 is 10. This
    is the same rate obtained from investing in a
    one-year bond

126
Features of PET
  • Similarly, the expected rate of return from
    holding a three-year bond for one year, then
    selling it at the implied forward rate of f21 is
    also 10. That is
  • Any of the bonds with spot rates shown in the
    exhibit would have expected rates for one year
    of 10 if the implied forward rate were used as
    the estimated expected rate.

127
Features of PET
  • Similarly, any bond held for two years and sold
    at its forward rate would earn the two-year spot
    rate of 10.5. For example, a four-year bond
    purchased at the spot rate of 11.5 and expected
    to be sold two years later at f22 12.5, would
    trade at an expected rate of 10.5 - the same as
    the current two-year spot.

128
Features of PET
  • Analysts often refer to forward rates as hedgable
    rates.
  • The most practical use of forward rates or
    expected spot yield curves generated from forward
    rates is that they provide cut-off rates, useful
    in evaluating investment decisions.
  • For example, an investor with a one-year horizon
    date should only consider investing in the
    two-year bond in our above example, if she
    expected one-year rates one year later to be less
    than f11 11 that is, assuming she is
    risk-averse and wants an expected rate greater
    than 10.
  • Thus, forward rates serve as a good cut-off rate
    for evaluating investments.

129
Websites
  • Historical interest rate data on different bonds
    can be found at the Federal Reserve site
    www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm
  • and www.research.stlouisfed.org/fred2
  • For information on Federal Reserve policies go to
  • www.federalreserve.gov/policy.htm
  • For information on European Central Banks go to
  • www.ecb.int

130
Websites
  • Current and historical data on U.S. government
    expenditures and revenues can be found at
    www.gpo.gov/usbudget.
  • Yield curves can be found at a number of
    siteswww.ratecurve.com and www.bloomberg.com
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)