Review of Theories of Financial Crises: Currency Crises - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 66
About This Presentation
Title:

Review of Theories of Financial Crises: Currency Crises

Description:

Consequently, there is one equilibrium with a speculative attack and a collapse of the regime, and there is another equilibrium, where these things do not happen. – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:210
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 67
Provided by: katz61
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Review of Theories of Financial Crises: Currency Crises


1
Review of Theories of Financial Crises Currency
Crises
  • By Itay Goldstein and Assaf Razin
  • June 2013

2
Scope
  • The last few years have been characterized by a
    great turmoil in the worlds financial markets
  • These events exhibit ingredients from all types
    of financial crises in recent history
  • Banking crises
  • National currency and single currency area crises
  • Credit frictions
  • Market freezes
  • Asset bubbles booms and Busts
  • Sovereign Debt Crises cum Eurocrisis

3
Financial and Monetary institutions
  • --Enable the efficient transmission of resources
    from savers to the best investment opportunities.
  • --Provide risk sharing possibilities, so that
    investors
  • can take more risk and advance the economy.
  • --Enable aggregation of information that provides
    guidance for more efficient investment decisions.
  • --Monetary arrangements, such as the European
    Monetary Union (EMU) are created to facilitate
    free trade and financial transactions among
    countries, thereby improving real efficiency.

4
Financial Crisis
  • A financial crisis marks a severe disruption of
    these normal functions of financial and monetary
    systems, thereby hurting the normal functioning
    of the real economy.

5
Financial Fragility
  • The models reviewed here describe situations in
    which financial systems are fragile and prone to
    crises.
  • Main problems
  • Agency problems
  • Those who are making the decisions
    might not fully reflect the interests of those
    on whose behalf they were supposed to be acting.
  • Coordination failures
  • e.g., Banks rely on the fact that only
    forecastable fraction of depositors will have
    short term liquidity needs. But there is self
    fulfilling equilibrium where all depositors
    demand early withdrawal.
  • Strategic Complementarities
  • E.g., When more depositors withdraw their
    money the bank is more likely to fail and so
    other depositors have a stronger incentive to
    withdraw.

6
  • Principal-Agent moral hazard
  • e.g., The borrower has the ability to divert
    resources to himself at the expense of the
    creditor. This creates a limit on credit. The
    limit can get tightens when economic conditions
    worsen.
  • Risk Shifting
  • e.g., An investor who borrow to buy assets
    benefits from the upside while having limited
    exposure to the downside risk.
  • Heterogeneous beliefs and leverage
  • e.g., where the optimists-pessimists
    composition in the investor population shifts
    endogenously leverage bubbles are created and
    burst.
  • Fragile institutional of monetary and exchange
    rate arrangements
  • E.g. European Monetary System

7
Currency Crises
  • Governments/central banks try to maintain certain
    financial and monetary arrangements, most notably
    a fixed-exchange rate regime, or more recently, a
    regional monetary union. Their goal is to
    stabilize the economy or the region.
  • At times, these arrangements become unstable and
    collapse leading to debt crises and banking
    crises
  • The strand of the literature analyzes currency
    crises characterized by a speculative attack on a
    fixed exchange rate regime. The newer strand
    emphasizes banking and fiscal union as a backstop
    to single currency area crises.

8
The International-Finance Tri-Lemma
  • A tri-lemma is a situation in which someone faces
    the choice among three options, each of which
    comes with some inevitable choices because not
    all the three can be simultaneously accomplished.

9
Monetary Policy Options
  • First, make the countrys economy open to
    international capital flows, because by doing so
    they let investors diversify their portfolios
    overseas and achieve risk sharing. They also
    benefit from the expertise brought to the country
    by foreign investors.
  • Second, use an independent monetary policy as a
    tool to help stabilize inflation, output, and the
    financial sector in the economy. This is achieved
    as the central bank can increase the money supply
    and reduce interest rates when the economy is
    depressed, and reduce money growth and raise
    interest rates when it is overheated. Moreover,
    it can serve as a lender of last resort in case
    of financial panic.

10
Options
  • Third, maintain stability in the exchange rate.
    This is because a volatile exchange rate, at
    times driven by speculation, can be a source of
    broader financial volatility, and makes it harder
    for households and businesses to trade in the
    world economy and for investors to plan for the
    future.

11
Fixed exchange rate and capital mobility
  • By attempting to maintain a fixed exchange rate
    and capital mobility, the central bank loses its
    ability to control the interest rate or
    equivalently the monetary base its policy
    instruments as the interest rate becomes
    anchored to the world interest rate by the
    interest rate parity and the monetary base is
    automatically adjusted. This is the case of
    individual members of the EMU.

12
Monetary Control and Capital Mobility
  • In order to keep control over the interest rate
    or equivalently the money supply, the central
    bank has to let the exchange rate float freely,
    as in the case of the US.

13
Exchange Rate Stability and Monetary Control
  • If the central bank wishes to maintain both
    exchange rate stability and control over the
    monetary policy, the only way to do it is by
    imposing domestic credit controls and
    international capital controls, as in the case of
    China.

14
Currency Crises and the Tri-Lemma
  • Currency crises occur when the country is trying
    to maintain a fixed exchange rate regime with
    capital mobility, but faces conflicting policy
    needs, such as fiscal imbalances or fragile
    financial sector, that need to be resolved by
    independent monetary policy, and effectively
    shift the regime from the first solution of the
    tri-lemma described above to the second solution
    and the tri-lemma.

15
First-Generation Models of Currency Crises
  • This branch of models, the so-called first
    generation models of currency attacks was
    motivated by a series of events where fixed
    exchange rate regimes collapsed following
    speculative attacks, for example, the early
    1970s breakdown of the Bretton Wood global
    system.
  • The first paper here is the one by Krugman
    (1979).
  • He describes a government that tries to maintain
    a fixed exchange rate regime, but is subject to a
    constant loss of reserves, due to the need to
    monetize government budget deficits.

16
First-Generation Model of Currency Crises
  • These two features of the policy are
    inconsistent with each other, and lead to an
    eventual attack on the reserves of the central
    bank, that culminate in a collapse of the fixed
    exchange rate regime.
  • Flood and Garber (1984) extended and clarified
    the basic mechanism, suggested by Krugman (1979),
    generating the formulation that was widely used
    since then.

17
A First-Generation Model of Currency Crises
  • Recall that the asset-side of the central banks
    balance sheet at time t is composed of domestic
    assets BH,t
  • the domestic-currency value of foreign assets
    StBF,t
  • where St denotes the exchange rate, i.e., the
    value of foreign currency in terms of domestic
    currency.
  • The total assets have to equal the total
    liabilities of the central bank, which are, by
    definition, the monetary base, denoted as Mt.

18
Currency Crises First-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
.
  • Due to fiscal imbalances, the domestic assets
    grow in a fixed and exogenous rate
  • Because of perfect capital mobility, the domestic
    interest rate is determined through the interest
    rate parity, as follows
  • Where it denotes the domestic interest rate at
    time t and it denotes the foreign interest rate
    at time t.

19
Currency Crises First-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • The supply of money, i.e., the monetary base, has
    to be equal to the demand for money, which is
    denoted as L(it), a decreasing function of the
    domestic interest rate.
  • The inconsistency between a fixed exchange rate
    regime
  • with capital mobility, and the fiscal
    imbalances, comes due to the fact that the
    domestic assets of the central bank keep growing,
    but the total assets cannot change since the
    monetary base is pinned down by the demand for
    money, L(it), which is determined by the foreign
    interest rate it

20
Currency Crises First-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • Hence, the obligation of the central bank to keep
    financing the fiscal needs, puts downward
    pressure on the domestic interest rate, which, in
    turn, puts upward pressure on the exchange rate.
  • In order to prevent depreciation, the central
    bank has to intervene by reducing the inventory
    of foreign reserves.
  • Overall, decreases by the same amount as
    BH,t increases, so the monetary base remains the
    same.

21
Currency Crises First-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • The problem is that this process cannot continue
    forever, since the reserves of foreign currency
    have a lower bound.
  • Eventually, the central bank will have to abandon
    the solution of the tri-lemma through a fixed
    exchange rate regime and perfect capital mobility
    to a solution through flexible exchange rate with
    flexible monetary policy (i.e., flexible monetary
    base or equivalently domestic interest rate) and
    perfect capital mobility.

22
Currency Crises First-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • The analytical question is what is the critical
    level of domestic assets BH,T , and the
    corresponding period of time T, at which the
    fixed-exchange rate regime collapses.
  • This happens when the (conditionally) expected
    shadow exchange rate -defined as the flexible
    exchange rate under the assumption that the
    central banks foreign reserves reached their
    lower bound while the central bank keeps
    increasing the domestic assets to accommodate the
    fiscal needs -is equal to the pegged exchange
    rate.

23
Second-Generation Model of Currency Crises
  • Following the collapse of the ERM in the early
    1990s, which was characterized by the tradeoff
    between the declining activity level and
    abandoning the exchange rate management system,
    the so-called first-generation model of currency
    attacks did not seem suitable any more to explain
    the ongoing crisis phenomena.
  • This led to the development of the so-called
    second generation model of currency attacks,
    pioneered by Obstfeld (1994, 1996).

24
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • A basic idea here is that the governments policy
    is not just on automatic pilot like in Krugman
    (1979) above, but rather that the government is
    setting the policy endogenously, trying to
    maximize a well-specified objective function,
    without being able to fully commit to a given
    policy.
  • In this group of models, there are usually
    self-fulfilling multiple equilibria, where the
    expectation of a collapse of the fixed exchange
    rate regime leads the government to abandon the
    regime.
  • This is related to the Diamond and Dybvig (1983)
    model of bank runs, creating a link between these
    two strands of the literature.

25
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • Obstfeld (1996) discusses various mechanisms that
    can create the multiplicity of equilibria in a
    currency-crisis model. Let us describe one of
    them, which is inspired by Barro and Gordon
    (1983).
  • Suppose that the government minimizes a loss
    function of the following type
  • Here, y is the level of output, y is the target
    level of output, and e is the rate of
    depreciation, which in the model is equal to the
    inflation rate.

26
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • Hence, the interpretation is that the government
    is in a regime of zero depreciation (a fixed
    exchange rate regime). Deviating from this regime
    has two costs.
  • The first one is captured by the index function
    in the third term above, which says that there is
    a fixed cost in case the government depreciates
    the currency.
  • The second one is captured by the second term
    above, saying that there are costs to the economy
    in case of inflation.

27
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises

  • But, there is also a benefit the government
    wishes to reduce deviations from the target level
    of output, and increasing the depreciation rate
    above the expected level serves to boost output,
    via the Philips Curve.
  • This can be seen in the following expression,
    specifying how output is determined
  • Here, is the natural output, u is a random
    shock, and is the expected level of
    depreciation/inflation that is set endogenously
    in the model by wage setters based on rational
    expectations

28
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • The idea is that an unexpected inflationary shock
    boosts output by reducing real wages and
    increasing production.
  • Importantly, the government cannot commit to a
    fixed exchange rate. Otherwise, it would achieve
    minimum loss by committing to e0.
  • However, due to lack of commitment, a sizable
    shock u will lead the government to depreciate
    and achieve the increase in output bearing the
    loss of credibility.

29
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • Going back to the tri-lemma discussed above, a
    fixed exchange rate regime prevents the
    government from using monetary policy to boost
    output, and a large enough shock will cause the
    government to deviate from the fixed exchange
    rate regime.
  • It can be shown that the above model generates
    multiplicity of equilibria. If wage setters
    coordinate on a high level of expected
    depreciation/inflation, then the government will
    validate this expectation with its policy by
    depreciating more often.

30
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • If they coordinate on a low level of expected
    depreciation, then the government will have a
    weaker incentive to deviate from the fixed
    exchange rate regime.
  • Hence, a depreciation becomes a self-fulfilling
    expectation.
  • Similarly, one can describe mechanisms where
    speculators may force the government to abandon
    an existing fixed-exchange rate regime by
    attacking its foreign currency reserves and
    making the maintenance of the regime too costly.
    If many speculators attack, the government will
    lose many reserves, and will be more likely to
    abandon the regime.

31
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • A self-fulfilling speculative attack is
    profitable only if many speculators join it.
  • Consequently, there is one equilibrium with a
    speculative attack and a collapse of the regime,
    and there is another equilibrium, where these
    things do not happen.
  • Similarly, speculators can attack government
    bonds demanding higher rates due to expected
    sovereign-debt default, creating an incentive for
    the central bank to abandon a currency regime and
    reduce the value of the debt.

32
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • As argued by Paul De Grauwe (2011), the problem
    can become more severe for countries that
    participate in a currency union since their
    governments do not have the independent monetary
    tools to reduce the cost of the debt.
  • Morris and Shin (1998) applied global games
    methods to tackle the problem of multiplicity of
    equilibrium in the second-generation models of
    speculative attacks.

33
Currency Crises Second-Generation Model of
Currency Crises
  • Using the global-game methodology, pioneered by
    Carlsson and van Damme (1993), they are able to
    derive a unique equilibrium, where the
    fundamentals of the economy uniquely determine
    whether a crisis occurs or not. This enabled them
    to ask questions as to the effect of policy
    tools on the probability of a currency attack.

34
Third generation Currency Crises models
  • While the 1st and 2nd generation currency crisis
    literature focused on the government alone, the
    Third-generation models connect currency crises
    to models of banking crises and credit frictions.

35
Twin Crises
  • In the late 1990s, a wave of crises hit the
    emerging economies in Asia, including Thailand,
    South Korea, Indonesia, Philippines, and
    Malaysia. A clear feature of these crises was the
    combination of the collapse of fixed exchange
    rate regimes, capital flows, financial
    institutions, and credit This led to extensive
    research on the interplay between currency and
    banking crises, sometimes referred to as the twin
    crises, and balance sheet effects of
    depreciations For a broad description of the
    events around the crisis, see Radelet and Sachs
    (1998). The importance of capital flows was
    anticipated by Calvo (1995).

36
Currency mismatch between their assets and
liabilities
  • One of the first models to capture this joint
    problem was presented in Krugman (1999).
  • In his model, firms suffer from a currency
    mismatch between their assets and liabilities
    their assets are denominated in domestic goods
    and their liabilities are denominated in foreign
    goods.
  • Then, a real exchange rate depreciation increases
    the value of liabilities relative to assets,
    leading to deterioration in firms balance
    sheets.

37
Add Credit Frictions
  • Because of credit frictions as in Holmstrom and
    Tirole (1997), described in the next section,
    this deterioration in firms balance sheets
    implies that they can borrow less and invest
    less.
  • The novelty in Krugmans paper is that the
    decrease in investment validates the real
    depreciation in the general- equilibrium setup.
  • This is because the decreased investment by
    foreigners in the domestic market implies that
    there will be a decrease in demand for local
    goods relative to foreign goods, leading to real
    depreciation.

38
Multiple Equilibrium
  • Hence, the system has a multiple equilibrium with
    high economic activity, appreciated exchange
    rate, and strong balance sheets in one
    equilibrium, and low economic activity,
    depreciated exchange rate, and weak balance
    sheets in the other equilibrium.
  • Other models that extended and continued this
    line of research include Aghion, Bacchetta, and
    Banerjee (2001), Caballero and Krishnamurthy
    (2001), and Schneider and Tornell (2004). The
    latter fully endogeneize the currency mismatch
    between firms assets and liabilities.

39
Third-Generation Model of Currency Crises
  • The global-game methodology, relying on
    heterogeneous information across speculators,
    also brought to the forefront the issue of
    information in currency-attack episodes, leading
    to analysis of the effect that transparency,
    signaling, and learning can have on such episodes
    (e.g., Angeletos, Hellwig, and Pavan (2006)).

40
Bank Runs and Currency Crises
  • Chang and Velasco (2001) and Goldstein (2004)
    model the vicious circle between bank runs and
    speculative attacks on the currency.
  • On the one hand, the expected collapse of the
    currency worsens banks prospects, as they have
    foreign liabilities and domestic assets, and thus
    generates bank runs, as described in the previous
    section. Bank runs are more likely in a currency
    union without a single-currency-wide bank union,
    or the ability of the central bank to act as a
    lender of last resort for sovereign debt.

41
Circular relationship between currency crises and
banking crises
  • On the other hand, the collapse of the banks
    leads to capital outflows that deplete the
    reserves of the government, encouraging
    speculative attacks against the currency.
  • Accounting for the circular relationship between
    currency crises and banking crises complicates
    policy analysis. For example, a
    lender-of-last-resort policy or other
    expansionary policies during a banking crisis
    might backfire as it depletes the reserves
    available to the government, making a currency
    crisis more likely, which in turn might further
    hurt the banking sector that is exposed to a
    currency mismatch.

42
Contagion of Currency Crises
  • The forceful transmission of crises across
    countries generated a large literature of
    international financial contagion.
  • Kaminsky, Reinhart, and Vegh (2003) provide a
    nice review of the theories behind such
    contagion. They define contagion as an immediate
    reaction in one country to a crisis in another
    country.
  • There are several theories that link such
    contagion to fundamental explanations.

43
Contagion of Currency Crises
  • The clearest one would be that there is common
    information about the different countries, and so
    the collapse in one country leads investors to
    withdraw out of other countries. For a broader
    review, see the collection of articles in
    Claessens and Forbes (2001).
  • Calvo and Mendoza (2000) present a model where
    contagion is a result of learning from the events
    in one country about the fundamentals in another
    country.

44
Contagion of Currency Crises
  • They argue that such learning is likely to occur
    when there is vast diversification of portfolios,
    since then the cost of gathering information
    about each country in the portfolio becomes
    prohibitively large, encouraging investors to
    herd.
  • Another explanation is based on trade links (see
    e.g., Gerlach and Smets (1995)).
  • If two countries compete in export markets, the
    devaluation of ones currency hurts the
    competitiveness of the other, leading it to
    devalue the currency as well. A third explanation
    is the presence of financial links between the
    countries.

45
Currency CrisesContagion
  • In Kodres and Pritsker (2002), investors optimize
    their portfolio allocation.
  • A decrease in the share of their portfolio held
    in one country due to a crisis, leads them to
    rebalance by reducing their holding in another
    country, and hence causes co-movement in prices.
  • In Allen and Gale (2000), different regions
    insure each other against excessive liquidity
    shocks, but this implies that a shock in one
    region is transmitted to the other region via the
    insurance linkage.

46
Currency CrisesContagion of Currency Crises
  • Empirical evidence has followed the above
    theories of contagion.
  • The common information explanation has vast
    support in the data.
  • Several of the clearest examples of contagion
    involve countries that appear very similar.
    Examples include the contagion that spread across
    East Asia in the late 1990s and the one in Latin
    America in the early 1980s. A vast empirical
    literature provides evidence that trade links can
    account for contagion to some extent.

47
Currency CrisesContagion of Currency Crises
  • These include Eichengreen, Rose, and Wyplosz
    (1996) and Glick and Rose (1999).
  • Others have shown that financial linkages are
    also empirically important in explaining
    contagion. For example, Kaminsky, Lyons, and
    Schmukler (2004) have shown that US-based mutual
    funds contribute to contagion by selling shares
    in one country when prices of shares decrease in
    another country.
  • Caramazza, Ricci, and Salgado (2004), Kaminsky
    and Reinhart (2000) and Van Rijckeghem and Weder
    (2003) show similar results for common commercial
    banks.

48
Single Currency Area Theory
  • In the 1960s, a new concept emerged in
    international macroeconomics
  • optimum currency area theory.
  • The question it sought to answer when should
    countries adopt a common
  • currency?
  • Recall that by adopting a common currency,
    countries would give up much of their policy
    independence the question was how costly that
    would be, and how large are the benefits.
  • One variant, pushed by Ronald McKinnon, stressed
    the amount of trade the more two countries
    trade, the bigger the advantages of not having to
    change currencies, and arguably, also, the less
    adjustment is needed to correct trade imbalances.
    Another (actually the first paper on the
    subject), by Robert Mundell, stressed labor
    mobility you dont need as much policy
    independence if unemployed workers can move to
    where the jobs are. A third, stressed by my late
    colleague Peter Kenen, stressed fiscal
    integration if countries or regions share common
    budgets for major programs, there will be a lot
    of automatic compensation for
  • asymmetric shocks.

49
Public debt denominated in own, or in foreign,
currency
  • Paul De Grauwe notes that the benefits of
    retaining a currency on ones own manifest in the
    post-crisis interest rates paid on long-term
    public debt
  • The ratio of net public debt to gross domestic
    product of the UK and Spain are essentially
    identical. (IMF forecasts that in 2017, the ratio
    is 93 per cent for the UK and 95 per cent for
    Spain.)
  • Yet the yield on UK 10-year bonds is firmly under
    2 per cent among the lowest in UK history, and
    not much above Germanys but the yield on
    Spanish 10-year bonds, meanwhile, is about 5 per
    cent.

50
Lender of last resort
  • The ability and desire of the Bank of England to
    prevent outright default is more credible than
    that of the ECB an independent, supranational
    central bank.
  • The BoE, as lender of last resort, also promises
    market liquidity. If the market for public debt
    is subject to self-fulfilling prophecies of good
    or bad outcomes, this should guarantee more
    stability at favorable rates.

51
Banks and Governments
  • Central Banks were given double task
  • ?Lender of last resort for banks
  • backstop to counter panic and run on banks.
  • ?Lender of last resort to governments
  • to counter run on government bond markets

52
Banks and Governments
  • Banks and governments face similar problem
    unbalanced maturity structure of assets and
    liabilities
  • ?Making both banks and governments vulnerable for
    movements of distrust, which will lead to
    liquidity crisis, and can degenerate into
    solvency crisis.
  • When banks collapse sovereign is in trouble
  • When government collapses banks are in trouble

53
A Need for Fiscal Union
  • The fiscal union aspect comes in because of the
    need to have government budget as shock absorber
    based on Keynes savings paradox paradox
  • ?When after crash private sector has to
    de-leverage. It does two things
  • ?It tries to save more.
  • ?It sells assets.
  • ?Private sector can only save more if government
    sector borrows more (i.e. higher budget deficit)
  • ?But, if government also tries to save more,
    attempts to save more by private sector are
    self-defeating. The economy is pulled into
    deflationary spiral.

54
Eurozone Stabilizers are organized at national
levels
  • These stabilizing features relatively well
    organized at the level of countries (US, UK,
    France, Germany), but, not at international level
    nor at the level of a monetary union like the
    Eurozone
  • ?These EMU design failures were only recognized
    after the financial crisis, also because Optimum
    Currency Area Theory was pre-occupied with
    exogenous shocks, but not with an endogenous
    dynamics
  • ?And even then in many countries, especially in
    Northern Europe the point is still not recognized
    because of dramatic diagnostic failure, focusing
    on government profligacy giving rise to
    austerity policy during the de-leveraging period.

55
Features that magnify private- and public-sector
financial fragility within the euro zone
  • Financial integration undermines the ability of
    individual member governments credibly to
    backstop their
  • national banking systems through purely fiscal
    means.
  • Within the euro zone the key functions of bank
    regulations, depositor insurance, bank
    resolutions and fiscal policy remained national.
  • In the absence of national discretion over
    last-resort lending, money creation, and the
  • exchange rate.

56
A Fiscal Tri-lemma
  • Obstfeld proposes a fiscal trilemma for the euro
    zone
  • One cannot simultaneously maintain all three (1)
    Cross-border financial integration
  • (2) Financial stability
  • (3) National fiscal independence.

57
Financial integration and financial stability
with external fiscal support
  • If countries are financially integrated,
  • they simply cannot credibly backstop their
    financial systems without the certainty of
    external fiscal support, either directly (from
    partner country treasuries) or indirectly
    (through monetary financing from the union-wide
    central bank) thus sacrificing national fiscal
    independence .

58
Alternatively, a country reliant mainly on its
own fiscal resources will likely sacrifice
financial integration as well as stability,
because markets will then assess financial risks
along national lines.
59
Financial repression to minimize financial
fragility
  • Voluntary withdrawal from the single financial
    market might allow a country with limited
  • fiscal space to control and insulate its
    financial sector enough to minimize fragility.

60
Fragility of government bond market in a
monetary union
  • Governments of member states cannot guarantee to
    bond holders that cash would always be there to
    pay them out at maturity in contrast with
    stand-alone countries that give this implicit
    guarantee, because they can and will force
    central bank to provide liquidity
  • (There is no limit to money creating capacity)

61
Self-fulfilling Sovereign Debt crises
  • This lack of implicit guarantee to government
    debt can trigger liquidity crises.
  • Because,
  • (1) distrust by market leads to bond sales, and
    interest rate increases.
  • (2) Liquidity is withdrawn from national markets,
    moving to safe havens.
  • Government, unable to rollover debt, is forced to
    introduce immediate and intense austerity,
    producing deep recession and Government Debt to
    GDP ratio increases.

62
In 2012 ECB has acted
  • On September 6, 2012 ECB announced it will buy
    unlimited amounts of government bonds.
  • ?Program is called Outright Monetary
    Transactions (OMT)
  • ?Large parts of the euro area were in a bad
    equilibrium in which self-fulfilling expectations
    were feeding on themselves.

63
Outright Monetary Transactions
  • European Central Banks promises to intervene via
    a program called outright monetary transactions
    (OMT). But, OMT is still less credible than
    lending of last resort by national central bank
    because in the context of supranational EMU
    institution there is no similar institution which
    provides a Eurozone fiscal backing.

64
Concluding Remarks
65
Far From a Fiscal Union Austerity in the
periphery to offset by stimulus in the core?
  • Source IMF
  •  

66
Thank you
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com