Maximin Utility with Renewable and Nonrenewable Resources - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Maximin Utility with Renewable and Nonrenewable Resources

Description:

Maximin Utility with Renewable and Nonrenewable Resources Jon M. Conrad In the spirit of Rawls (1971): If you did not know the generation into which you would be born ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:51
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 25
Provided by: Auth92
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Maximin Utility with Renewable and Nonrenewable Resources


1
Maximin Utility with Renewable and Nonrenewable
Resources
  • Jon M. Conrad

2
In the spirit of Rawls (1971)
  • If you did not know the generation into which you
    would be born, what rules would you want society
    to adopt relating to consumption, the rate of
    harvest from a renewable resource, and the rate
    of extraction from a nonrenewable resource?
  • You might want rates of consumption harvest, and
    extraction which maximized the utility of the
    least-well-off generation. This is known as the
    maximin criterion.
  • In this paper, Conrad numerically explores the
    maximin criterion in a discrete-time model with a
    renewable and a nonrenewable resource and a
    finite number of non-overlapping generations.

3
The Rawlsian social contract
  • Takes the form of a vector of four rates
  • a the fraction of a manufactured good that is
    consumed
  • ß the fraction of a renewable resource that is
    harvested
  • ?F the fraction of a nonrenewable resource
    extracted for production of the manufactured
    good, and
  • ?U the fraction of the nonrenewable resource
    extracted for direct consumption (utility).
  • These rates are adopted by all generations.

4
The maximin social contract
  • The maximin social contract does not lead to
    equal utility across a finite number of
    generations
  • But it typically results in an equitable
    intergenerational distribution of utility, as
    measured by the Gini coefficient.
  • We explore how the four rates in the maximin
    social contract depend on initial conditions and
    the number of generations.

5
Introduction
  • Rawls (1971) asked what social contract one would
    want in place if
  • "no one knows his place in society, his class
    position or social status, nor does anyone know
    his fortune in the distribution of natural assets
    and abilities, his intelligence, strength, and
    the like. The principles of justice are chosen
    behind a veil of ignorance." (Rawls, 1971, p.11.)
  • To Rawls, the rational individual, not knowing
    his or her lot in life, would want rules in place
    that would maximize the utility of the
    least-well-off individual.
  • This is now referred to as the maximin criterion.

6
II. The Model (a)
  • Yt F(Kt ,QF, t )
  • the output of the manufactured good by the tth
    generation.
  • i.e. output is a function of the capital stock,
    Kt , and the rate of extraction from a
    nonrenewable resource, QF, t
  • Population and work force are constant and
    unchanging through time.
  • Ct aF(Kt ,QF, t )
  • the consumption of manufactured goods, a gt 0
  • Ht ßXt
  • the harvest from a renewable resource of size Xt
    , 1 gt ß gt 0
  • Ut U(Ct ,Ht ,QU, t )
  • Utility of the tth generation depends on
    consumption of the manufactured good, harvest
    from the renewable resource, and QU, t
    (extraction from the nonrenewable resource
    consumed directly by the tth generation)

7
  • QF, t ?FRt and QU, t ?URt
  • denote the levels of extraction for production of
    the manufactured good and for direct consumption
    when the remaining reserves of the nonrenewable
    resource are Rt
  • 1 gt ?F gt 0 , 1 gt ?U gt 0 , 1 gt (?F ?U ) gt
    0 ,
  • Rt1 1 - (?F ?U) Rt
  • the dynamics of remaining reserves,
  • Kt1 Kt (1- a)F(Kt ,QF, t )
  • the dynamics of the capital stock,

8
  • Xt1 1- ß r(1- Xt/Xc )Xt
  • the dynamics of the renewable resource
  • r gt 0 is the intrinsic growth rate
  • Xc gt 0 is the environmental carrying capacity
  • and it is assumed that 1- r ß lt 1 (to avoid
    chaos)
  • Let t 0,1,2,...,T be the number of generations
    under consideration, where t 0 is the current
    generation and T is the terminal generation
  • a, ß, ?F , ?U denotes a social contract,
    invariant across the generations.

9
The optimization problem
  • Seeks to find the social contract which will

10
Numerical analysis will require specification of
  • The production function and the utility function
  • and any parameters to those functions
  • The parameter values for r , Xc ,
  • The initial conditions, K0 , X0 , R0 , and T .
  • Assume Cobb-Douglas forms for both the production
    function and utility function
  • Yt F(Kt ,QF, t ) Kt?Q?F, t
  • Ut U(Ct ,Ht ,QU, t ) CteHt?QfU, t
  • where
  • 1 gt ? gt ? gt 0
  • 1 gt ? ?
  • 1 gt e gt 0
  • 1 gt ? gt 0 ,
  • 1 gt f gt 0

11
Properties
  • The production function and the utility
    function exhibit declining marginal product or
    utility, respectively, and both functions are
    homogeneous of degree less than one.
  • These functions both have unitary elasticity of
    substitution between inputs (in the case of the
    production function) or commodities (in the
    case of the utility function).
  • This will allow capital to substitute for
    extraction of the nonrenewable resource in
    production
  • And for consumption or harvest to substitute for
    extraction from the nonrenewable resource in
    utility.
  • In the social contract, a, ß, ?F , ?U, a
    positive, steady-state, level for Xt will be
    achieved at
  • X Xc (r - ß)/r

12
III. The Gini Coefficient
  • The Gini coefficient is a statistical measure of
    dispersion, commonly used to measure income
    inequality within a country.
  • Consider the 45º line and the Lorenz Curve, L(X)
    , drawn in Figure 1.
  • On the horizontal axis, moving from left to
    right, the population of a country is ordered
    from lowest income to highest income. The Lorenz
    Curve plots the cumulative share of income earned
    by the poorest X of the population.
  • If earned income were equally distributed, the
    Lorenz Curve would be the 45º line.
  • If the poorest X of the population earned Y of
    the income, where Y lt X, for X lt 1 100 , then
    the Lorenz Curve is convex and lies below the 45º
    line.
  • The area below the 45º line and above the Lorenz
    Curve is the Gini coefficient divided by two
    (G/2).
  • If one person earned all the income, the Lorenz
    Curve becomes the X and Y axes, the area below
    the 45º line is one-half, and G 1.
  • If income were equally distributed, the Gini
    coefficient would be zero.
  • Thus, higher Gini coefficients imply greater
    inequality.

13
(No Transcript)
14
More on Gini
15
IV. Maximin Social Contracts
  • To start, we consider a simple maximin problem
    where T 10 , implying that 11 generations will
    be bound by the social contact a, ß, ?F , ?U.
  • Table 1 shows an initial spreadsheet where the
    social contract has been arbitrarily set to a,
    ß, ?F , ?U 0.90, 0.20, 0.05, 0.05 , as
    indicated by the values in cells I8I11
  • Other parameter values are shown in cells B3B13.

16
(No Transcript)
17
Simulation 1
  • Given these parameter values, initial conditions,
    and the social contract, the spreadsheet in
    Table 1 simulates the values for consumption,
    harvest from the renewable resource, extraction
    for utility, extraction for production, the
    capital stock, remaining reserves, and utility in
    columns B through I.
  • Column J indicates the rank of each utility level
    and column K computes the term (T 2 - RankUt
    )Ut , whose sum will be used in computing the
    Gini coefficient.
  • In cells I28I30 we use the Excel functions
    MIN(I16I26) to return the minimum utility,
    MAX(I16I26) to return the maximum utility
    (just for comparison to the minimum), and compute
    the Gini coefficient for the utility vector using
    Equation (2).
  • For this initial social contract we see utility
    monotonically declines from U0 3.28787 to U10
    2.86017 .
  • The Gini coefficient registers G 0.02357 .
  • In this initial spreadsheet, the steady-state
    stock for the renewable resource is X 80 ,
    which is reached in t 1.

18
Simulation 1 (Optimised)
  • We now use Excels Solver to maximize the minimum
    utility in cell I28 by changing the social
    contract in cells I8I11.
  • The maximin social contract and time paths for
    consumption, harvest, extraction, the capital
    stock, remaining reserves, and utility are given
    in Table 2. For this numerical example the
    maximin social contract is given by a, ß, ?F ,
    ?U 0.634, 0.5, 0.082, 0.087 . The maximized
    minimum utility is U2 3.87149 .
  • Perhaps surprisingly, we see that the maximin
    social contract is Pareto superior to the initial
    social contact in that all utility levels have
    been increased.
  • When the initial stock of the renewable resource
    exceeds the stock necessary to support maximum
    sustainable yield, XMSY , the maximin social
    contract will choose ß so that X XMSY Xc/2 .
    But, as noted above, X Xc (r - ß)/ r . With r
    1, equating these last two expressions for X
    implies ß 0.5.
  • Under the maximin social contract, the
    nonrenewable resource has been depleted to a
    lower level than in the initial spreadsheet, R10
    15.84645 lt 34.86784 , while the terminal capital
    stock is higher, K10 15.39637 gt 2.97142 .
  • Finally, the Gini coefficient is slightly lower
    under the maximin contract ( 0.02180 lt 0.02357 )
    indicating slightly more equitable time paths for
    consumption, harvest, and extraction.

19
(No Transcript)
20
Maximin Social Contract
  • Why, in a finite-generation model, is it is not
    optimal to completely exhaust the nonrenewable
    resource. As Rt is reduced so too are the
    extraction levels, QF, t ?F Rt and Q U, t
    ?URt , leading to lower levels for QU, t and Ut .
    With all generations committed to the maximin
    social contract, compensating adjustments in
    consumption of the manufactured good or harvest
    of the renewable resource are more limited than
    if rates of consumption, harvest and extraction
    were allowed to vary over time. Complete
    exhaustion in T 10 would cause U10 0 . With
    the objective of maximizing the minimum utility,
    this is not optimal. Remaining reserves can only
    be depleted so far before the utility of later
    generations is reduced below the minimum utility
    under the maximin social contract.
  • Solow (1974) noted the importance of initial
    conditions in the maximin problem.
  • In the initial spreadsheet in Table 1, we
    arbitrarily set K(0) K0 1, R(0) R0 100 ,
    and X(0) X0 100 . We will refer to this
    initial condition as the less developed,
    resource-rich initial condition.
  • For contrast, we consider two other initial
    conditions
  • K(0) K0 1,R(0) R0 100 , and X(0) X0
    40 , the less developed, nonrenewable rich
    initial condition
  • K(0) K0 100 , R(0) R0 40 , and X(0) X0
    40 ,the developed, resource-depleted initial
    condition.
  • We compute the maximin social contract for these
    three initial conditions for T 10, 20, 50 . We
    are interested in how individual rates within the
    social contract change with a change in the
    initial condition and in the horizon length
    (number of generations). The results are shown in
    Table 3.

21
(No Transcript)
22
What can be gleaned from Table 3?
  • Most consistent result an increase in T causes
    a reduction in both ?F and ?U . This makes sense,
    as the nonrenewable resource must be spread over
    a longer horizon for future generations to have
    positive production and utility.
  • When X0 gt XMSY Xc/2 , the maximin social
    contract will always select a ß so that X Xc
    (r - ß)/ r XMSY Xc/2 . With r 1 this
    implies ß 0.5 . We see this rate of harvest for
    all T with the less-developed-resource-rich
    initial conditions (first row in Table 3) and,
    more surprisingly, in the developed-resource-depl
    eted initial conditions (the third row in Table
    3).
  • Consumption of the manufactured good involves 1 gt
    a gt 0 in all cases except for the
    developed-resource-depleted case when T 10 . In
    this case the maximin social contract sets a
    1.05621, which results in each generation
    consuming more of the manufactured good (capital)
    than is produced, with the result that the stock
    of capital declines from its relatively abundant
    initial condition of K(0) K0 100 to K10
    91.67416 . With abundant capital and a relatively
    short horizon, this social contract makes sense.
    If you can achieve a higher minimum utility by
    eating your capital stock, do so. For longer
    horizons (T 20 and T 50 ) capital consumption
    in excess of production is no longer optimal in
    the maximin social contract.
  • In the less-developed-resource-rich and in the
    less-developed-nonrenewable-rich cases (rows one
    and two) the Gini coefficient increases as T
    increases. As the horizon increases for these
    initial conditions the utility profile assumes a
    low-high-low pattern. With T 50 , the peak
    utility level occurs in t 17 for all three
    initial conditions. In the developed-resource-depl
    eted case (the third row) the Gini coefficient
    decreases as T increases. In this row, when T
    10 , the utility profile monotonically declines
    as earlier generations obtain higher utility from
    higher levels of consumption of the initially
    abundant capital good. Comparing the maximized
    minimum utilities in the three rows of Table 3,
    if one could choose their initial conditions, but
    not the value of T, (a partial veil of
    ignorance), one would prefer to gamble on T
    starting from a developed resource-depleted
    initial state.
  • Finally, for the less-developed-nonrenewable-rich
    initial conditions, where R(0) R0 100 and
    X(0) X0 40 , we observe an increase in ß as T
    increases. This result may at first seem
    counter-intuitive. From a relatively low initial
    stock for the renewable resource one might think
    that the maximin contract would choose ß 0.5.
    Examination of the utility profiles provides the
    answer. In all three cases in row two of Table 3,
    the minimum utility is U0. The least costly way
    to increase the utility of this first generation
    is to bump up the initial harvest from the
    renewable resource which is only possible if X0 gt
    X Xc (r ß)/r . With X(0) X0 40 , this
    requires ß gt 0.6 .
  • In all three cases in row two H0 gt Ht , for t
    1,2,...,T and this pattern of harvest is required
    to maximize the minimum utility, U0 .

23
Conclusions
  • The model lead to an operational definition of
    the Rawlsian social contract. The social
    contract became a vector of rates of consumption,
    harvest, extraction for production of the
    manufactured good and extraction for direct
    utility. It was a social contract because it was
    adopted by all generations.
  • The maximin social contract maximized the minimum
    generational utility over the horizon t
    0,1,...,T .
  • While an analytic solution for the maximin social
    contract was not possible, the problem could be
    programmed on an Excel spreadsheet and easily
    solved for modest values of T .
  • Is there anything to be learned from this simple
    model? Perhaps.
  • When adding a renewable resource to the maximin
    problem, if there is no cost to harvest and if
    X0gt XMSY , the maximin social contract would move
    the resource stock to the level that supports
    maximum sustainable yield. This adjustment takes
    place in t 0 where H0 (X0 ! XMSY ) and then
    Xt XMSY and Ht HMSY for t ! 1 regardless of
    the value for T .
  • If X 0 lt XMSY the harvest rate ß may be greater
    than the rate associated with maximum sustainable
    yield if it is the least-cost way to increase Min
    Ut U0 .
  • Does the finite horizon in this computational
    model diminish it relevance. I think not. The
    difficulty with making sustainable choices when
    one cares about future generations is that we
    dont know the stocks that future generations
    will find essential or desirable. We dont know
    the preferences of future generations nor the
    technologies which will influence the value of
    manufactured or natural capital in the future.
  • Uncertainty about preferences and technology make
    maximin over an infinite horizon an elegant
    exercise of questionable relevance. It may be
    better to build finite-horizon models with
    greater reality in their economic and resource
    structure and explore, computationally, maximin
    in greater detail.

24
References
  • dAutume, A. and K. Schubert. 2008. Hartwicks
    Rule and Maximin Paths when the Exhaustible
    Resource has Amenity Value, Journal of
    Environmental Economics and Management, 56(3)
    260-274.
  • Hartwick, J. M. 1977. Intergenerational Equity
    and the Investing of Rents from Exhaustible
    Resources, American Economic Review,
    66(5)972-974.
  • Rawls, J. 1971. A Theory of Justice, Harvard
    University Press, Cambridge.
  • Solow, R. M. 1974. Intergenerational Equity and
    Exhaustible Resources, Review of Economic
    Studies (Symposium on the Economics of
    Exhaustible Resources), 29-45.
  • Withagen, C and G. B. Asheim. 1998.
    Characterizing Sustainability The Converse of
    Hartwicks Rule, Journal of Economic Dynamics
    and Control, 23159-165.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com