Hyperbolic Discounting: Fact or Artefact : Experimental Evidence from Ethiopia

1 / 22
About This Presentation
Title:

Hyperbolic Discounting: Fact or Artefact : Experimental Evidence from Ethiopia

Description:

... by written questionnaire in developed country studies, coupled with the lottery ... experiment conducted in collaboration between EDRI and University of Maryland. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:113
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 23
Provided by: ran277

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Hyperbolic Discounting: Fact or Artefact : Experimental Evidence from Ethiopia


1
Hyperbolic Discounting Fact or Artefact
Experimental Evidence from Ethiopia
  • (Co-authored with Heather Klemich and John List)
  • Presenting Author Mahmud Yesuf
  • November 8, 2007, Monkey Valley Resort,
  • Cape Town, South Africa

2
Background and motivation
  • Individual rates of time preference have
    important implications in developing countries,
    from savings to investment to conservation
    decisions thereby hindering wealth accumulation
    and hastening natural resource degradation.
  • Numerous experimental studies lend credence to
    the hyperbolic discounting in that individuals
    are impatient about immediate or near-term
    consumption decisions but relatively more patient
    over future consumption.

3
Motivation (cont)
  • Ex Subjects often prefer to receive 1 today
    than 2 a month from now but also prefer 2 in 13
    months to 1 in 12 months.
  • This is inconsistent time preference.
  • Few studies have examined inconsistent time
    preferences in developing countries, where
    discount rates are more likely to diverge from
    market interest rates due to pervasive capital
    market imperfections.

4
Motivation (cont)
  • Existing experimental evidence on rates of time
    preference has a number of limitations that call
    into question whether the observed behaviors can
    be taken as indications of true time preferences
    or as predictable responses to confounding
    factors.

5
Some weaknesses of existing studies
  • Many experiments use hypothetical rewards, which
    may bias results if participants respond
    differently to hypothetical and real situations.
  • Studies offering an immediate payment option as
    the near-term reward cannot establish whether
    hyperbolic behavior results from discount rates
    that truly vary over the time horizon or from
    avoidance of transaction costs and uncertainty
    about the researchers trustworthiness associated
    with receiving a delayed payment.
  • A long series of questions, typically
    administered by written questionnaire in
    developed country studies, coupled with the
    lottery payment mechanism, may lead to anomalies
    caused by confusion or misunderstandings when
    asked verbally, as is common in surveys in rural
    areas of developing countries where a high
    proportion of participants may be
    illiterate(Ashraf, Karlan and Yin 2006)
  • Background risk if payments are made using
    lotteries (Harrison, List and Towe 2007)

6
Weaknesses (cont)
  • Perhaps more serious is the issue of whether time
    preferences can even be elicited through
    experiments using money. Hyperbolic consumption
    preferences do not imply hyperbolic preferences
    for wealth if subjects participate in markets. In
    experiments with money or tradable goods,
    exponential and hyperbolic discounters alike have
    incentives to choose the reward that will
    maximize wealth and trade for the preferred
    consumption bundle in the marketplace (Mulligan
    1996)
  • Confounding factors like the availability of
    complements over time and expected future
    consumption flows (Besharov and Coffey 2003).
  • Discount rates inferred from monetary experiments
    may also be biased upwards if researchers do not
    account for inflation (Besharov and Coffey 2003).
  • We conduct an artefactual field experiment in
    rural Ethiopia designed to address these
    limitations.

7
Our contributions
  • We offer real payments of a substantial sum to
    motivate responses with real consequences.
  • We vary payments between cash, tradable
    consumption goods, and final consumption goods to
    discern whether subjects responses
    systematically differ between tradable and
    non-tradable rewards.
  • We introduce a front-end delay treatment to
    compare whether revealed discount rates change
    when the near-term payment is delivered with a
    short delay (one week in our experiment) instead
    of immediately to control for any uncertainty or
    transaction costs associated with collecting a
    delayed reward.

8
Contributions (cont)
  • We control for subjects expected changes in
    seasonal consumption flows by setting the future
    time frame one year from the near-term.
  • We avoid the misunderstandings and background
    risk that may arise from questionnaires that ask
    a series of questions with different time frames
    and determine the reward by randomly choosing one
    of the responses, opting instead for a simple
    two-question design.
  • Our design can only identify the upper or lower
    bound of respondents discount rates, allowing us
    to classify respondents as patient or
    impatient,.

9
Study Sites
  • The data for this paper come from two surveys
    conducted in parallel on a random selection of
    445 households from the Eastern Gojjam zone of
    the Northwestern Ethiopian Highlands a household
    survey on sustainable land use from a
    Sida/SAREC-funded collaborative research project
    between the Ethiopian Development Research
    Institute (EDRI) and Goteborg University, Sweden,
    and a real-payoff discounting experiment
    conducted in collaboration between EDRI and
    University of Maryland.
  • The surveys were conducted in March-April 2006.

10
Study sites (cont)
Mean characteristics of our samples
11
Experimental Design
12
Experimental Questions
  • Experimental questions Monetary treatment
  • A
  • 1. Would you prefer to receive ETB13 today or ETB
    17 in one month?
  • 2. Would you prefer to receive ETB13 in 12 months
    or ETB 17 in 13 months?
  • B
  • 1. Would you prefer to receive ETB 13 in one week
    or ETB 17 in one week and one month?
  • 2. Would you prefer to receive ETB 13 in 12
    months or ETB 17 in 13 months?

13
Experimental Questions (cont)
  • Experimental questions Tradable treatment
  • C
  • 1. Would you prefer to receive 8 kg of wheat
    today or 11 kg of wheat in one month?
  • 2. Would you prefer to receive 8 kg of wheat in
    12 months or 11 kg of wheat in 13 months?
  • D
  • 1. Would you prefer to receive 8 kg of wheat in
    one week or 11 kg of wheat in one week and one
    month?
  • 2. Would you prefer to receive 8 kg of wheat in
    12 months or 11 kg of wheat in 13 months?

14
Experimental Questions (cont)
  • Experimental questions Final consumption good
    treatment
  • E
  • 1. Would you prefer to receive 9.5 kg of salt
    today or 13.5 kg of salt in one month?
  • 2. Would you prefer to receive 9.5 kg of salt in
    12 months or 13.5 kg of salt in 13 months?
  • F
  • 1. Would you prefer to receive 9.5 kg of salt in
    one week or 13.5 kg of salt in one week and one
    month?
  • 2. Would you prefer to receive 9.5 kg of salt in
    12 months or 13.5 kg of salt in 13 months?

15
Results
Responses to all treatments combined
No evidence of time preference reversal
16
Results (cont)

Number () of subjects choosing patient option,
by question order
Pearson chi2(1) 136.4759 Pr 0.000
Time preference vary based on order of question.
But anchoring effect observed
17
Results (cont)
Number () of subjects choosing patient option,
immediate vs. front-end delay option
Pearson chi2(1) 5.4144 Pr 0.020
Significant d/ce in degree of patience when front
end delay is added. But anchoring effect preclude
conclusions that hyperbolic discounting in other
studies is due to transaction cost and risk of
delayed payments
18
Results (cont)
Cash vs. wheat or salt
Pearson chi2(1) 1.6926 Pr 0.193
No significant difference across the mode of
payments though, in general, impatient over cash
than consumption goods. Probably limited
arbitrage in ETH.
19
Results (cont)
Wheat vs. salt
Pearson chi2(1) 0.1998 Pr 0.655
No significant difference across consumption goods
20
Determinants of patience
  • probit.pdf

21
Conclusions
  • Not strong and consistent evidence of hyperbolic
    discountung.
  • Imputed time preferences change with changes in
    the order of questions, and when front end delay
    is added to the experiment.
  • Whether lack of front end delay (thereby risk and
    transaction cost) causes hyperbolic discounting
    in other studies is precluded because of
    anchoring effect.
  • We find no difference in elicited time
    preferences between cash and consumption goods,
    whether tradable or final. This finding could
    result from the limited intertemporal arbitrage
    opportunities available in rural Ethiopia due to
    missing markets.
  • Wealth is strong determinant of patience.

22
Thank You!
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)