ECO 120- Macroeconomics - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 130
About This Presentation
Title:

ECO 120- Macroeconomics

Description:

... goods in their final form (so we don't count sales of milk to cheese-makers) ... Sam injures his back and is forced to take a lighter work-load, so their ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:107
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 131
Provided by: roddu
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: ECO 120- Macroeconomics


1
ECO 120- Macroeconomics
  • Weekend School 1
  • 21st April 2007
  • Lecturer Rod Duncan
  • Previous version of notes PK Basu

2
Topics for discussion
  • Module 1- macroeconomic variables
  • Module 2- basic macroeconomic models
  • Module 3- savings and investment
  • What will not be discussed
  • Answers to Assignment 1 (use the CSU forum for
    this)

3
Forms of economics
  • Microeconomics- the study of individual
    decision-making
  • Should I go to college or find a job?
  • Should I rob this bank?
  • Why are there so many brands of margarine?
  • Macroeconomics- the study of the behaviour of
    large-scale economic variables
  • What determines output in an economy?
  • What happens when the interest rate rises?

4
Economics as story-telling
  • In a story, we have X happens, then Y happens,
    then Z happens.
  • In an economic story or model, we have X happens
    which causes Y to happen which causes Z to
    happen.
  • There is still a sequence and a flow of events,
    but the causation is stricter in the economic
    story-telling.

5
Kobe, the naughty dog
6
Modelling Kobe
  • Kobe likes to unmake the bed.
  • Kobe likes treats.
  • We assume that more treats will lead to fewer
    unmade beds.
  • (Not a very good) Model
  • Treats? ? Unmaking the bed?
  • We can use this model to explain the past or to
    predict the future.

7
Elements of a good story
  • All stories have three parts
  • Beginning- description of how things are
    initially- the initial equilibrium.
  • Middle- we have a shock to the system, and we
    have some process to get us to a new equilibrium.
  • End- description of how things are at the new
    final equilibrium- the story stops.
  • Equilibrium- a system at rest.

8
Timeframes in economics
  • In economics we also talk in terms of three
    timeframes
  • short run- the period just after a shock has
    occurred where a temporary equilibrium holds.
  • medium run- the period during which some
    process is pushing the economy to a new long run
    equilibrium.
  • long run- the economy is now in a permanent
    equilibrium and stays there until a new shock
    occurs.
  • You have to have a solid understanding of the
    equilibrium and the dynamic process of a model.

9
What are the big questions?
  • What drives people to study macroeconomics? They
    want solutions to problems such as
  • Can we avoid fluctuations in the economy?
  • Why do we have inflation?
  • Can we lower the unemployment rate?
  • How can we manage interest rates?
  • Is the foreign trade deficit a problem?
  • How can we make the economy grow faster? Not
    taken up in this class. This class focuses on
    short-run problems.

10
Economic output
  • Gross domestic product- The total market value of
    all final goods and services produced in a period
    (usually the year).
  • Market value- so we use the prices in markets
    to value things
  • Final- we only value goods in their final form
    (so we dont count sales of milk to
    cheese-makers)
  • Goods and services- both count as output

11
Measuring GDP
  • Are we 40 times (655/16) better off than our
    grandparents?
  • Australian GDP in 1960- 15.6 billion
  • Australian GDP in 2000- 655.6 billion
  • What are we forgetting to adjust for?

12
Measuring GDP
  • Population- Australias population was 10 million
    in 1960 and 19 million in 2000.
  • GDP per person in 1960 15.6 bn / 10m
    1,560
  • GDP per person in 2000 655.6 bn / 19m
  • 34,500
  • Prices- 1,000 in 1960 bought a better life-style
    than 1,000 in 2000.

13
Nominal versus real GDP
  • So how to correct for rising prices over time?
  • Measure average prices over time (GDP deflator,
    Consumer Price Index, Producer Price Index, etc)
  • Deflate nominal GDP by the average level of
    prices to find real GDP
  • Real GDP Nominal GDP / GDP Deflator

14
Nominal versus real GDP
  • We use prices to value output in calculating GDP,
    but prices change all the time. And over time,
    the average level of prices generally has risen
    (inflation).
  • Nominal GDP value of output at current prices
  • Real GDP value of output at some fixed set of
    prices

15
Some Australian economic history
16
Business cycle
  • The economy goes through fluctuations over time.
    This movement over time is called the business
    cycle.
  • Recession The time over which the economy is
    shrinking or growing slower than trend
  • Recovery The time over which the economy is
    growing more quickly than trend
  • Peak A temporary maximum in economic activity
  • Trough A temporary minimum in economic activity.

17
Australian business cycle
18
Unemployment
  • To be officially counted as unemployed, you
    must
  • Not currently have a job and
  • Be actively looking for a job
  • Labour force- the number of people employed
    plus those unemployed
  • Unemployment rate
  • (Number of unemployed)/(Labour force)

19
Unemployment
  • Working age population Labour force Not in
    labour force
  • Labour force Employed Unemployed

20
Unemployment
21
Inflation
  • Inflation is the rate of growth of the average
    price level over time.
  • But how do we arrive at an average price level?
  • The Consumer Price Index surveys consumers and
    derives an average level of prices based on the
    importance of goods for consumers, ie. a change
    in the price of housing matters a lot, but a
    change in the price of Tim Tams does not.

22
Consumer Price Index
  • Then the CPI expresses average prices each year
    relative to a reference year, which is a CPI of
    100.
  • CPIt (Average prices in year t)/(Average prices
    in reference year) x 100
  • Inflation can then be measured as the growth in
    CPI from the year before
  • Inflationt (CPIt CPIt-1) / CPIt-1

23
Inflation
24
Calculating GDP
  • Gross domestic product- The total market value of
    all final goods and services produced in a period
    (usually the year).
  • Alternates methods of calculating GDP
  • Income approach add up the incomes of all
    members of the economy
  • Value-added approach add up the value added to
    goods at each stage of production
  • Expenditure approach add up the total spent by
    all members of the economy
  • The expenditure approach forms the basis of the
    AD-AS model.

25
Expenditure approach
  • GDP is calculated as the sum of
  • Consumption expenditure by households (C)
  • Investment expenditures by businesses (I)
  • Government purchases of goods and services (G)
  • Net spending on exports (Exports Imports) (NX)
  • Aggregate Expenditure AE C I G NX

26
Consumption and savings
  • We assume consumption (C) depends on households
    disposable income
  • Disposable income YD (Income Taxes)
  • The consumption function shows how C changes as
    YD changes.
  • Household savings (S) is the remainder of
    disposable income after consumption.
  • The savings function shows how S changes as YD
    changes.

27
Properties of a consumption function
  • What assumptions are we going to make about
    aggregate consumption of goods and services in an
    economy?
  • An aggregate consumption function is simply
    adding up all consumption functions of all
    individuals in society.
  • If personal income is 0, people consume a
    positive amount, through using up savings,
    borrowing from others, etc, so C(0) should be
    greater than 0.
  • As personal income rises, people spend more, so
    the slope of C(Y) should be positive.

28
Consumption function
  • Consumption is a function of YD or C C(YD). We
    assume that this relationship takes a linear
    (straight-line) form
  • C a b YD
  • where a is C when YD is zero and b is the
    proportion of each new dollar of YD that is
    consumed.
  • We assume that C is increasing in YD, so 0 lt b lt
    1.

29
A linear consumption function
  • C(Y) a b Y, a gt 0 and b gt 0

C(Y)
C(0) a, so even if Y0, C gt 0.
Slope is b gt 0, so C is increasing in Y.
a
Y
30
Graphing a function in Excel
  • This subject use a lot of quantitative data
    (which means lists of numbers measuring things).
  • Students will need to develop their quantitative
    skills-
  • Graphing data
  • Using data to support an argument
  • Modelling in Excel
  • We will be using Excel during this subject. You
    must become familiar with Excel.

31
Savings function
  • Household savings is a function of YD or S
    S(YD). We assume
  • S c d YD
  • where c is S when YD is zero and d is the
    proportion of each new dollar of YD that is
    saved.
  • We assume that S is increasing in YD, so 0 lt d lt
    1.
  • But also households must either consume or save
    their income, so C S YD. This can only be
    true if c -a and b d 1.

32
More terms
  • Average Propensity to Consume (APC) is
    consumption as a fraction of YD
  • APC C / YD
  • Average Propensity to Save (APS) is savings as a
    fraction of YD
  • APS S / YD
  • Since all disposable income is either consumed or
    saved, we have
  • APC APS 1

33
More terms
  • Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC) is the
    change in consumption as YD changes
  • MPC (Change in C) / (Change in YD)
  • Marginal Propensity to Save (APS) is the change
    in savings as YD changes
  • MPS (Change in S) / (Change in YD)
  • For our linear consumption and savings functions,
    MPC b and MPS d. If YD changes, then
    consumption and savings must change to use up all
    the change in YD , so
  • MPC MPS 1.

34
Graphing the functions
  • When YD 0, C S 0, so at point A, the
    intercept terms are both just below 2 and of
    opposite sign.
  • The 45 degree line in the top graph shows the
    level of YD. At point D, C is equal to YD, so S
    0.
  • MPC 0.75 is the slope of the C function.
  • MPS 0.25 is the slope of the S function.

35
What else determines C?
  • Household consumption will also depend on
  • Household wealth
  • Average price level of goods and services
  • Expectations about the future
  • Changes in these factors will produce a shift of
    the whole C and S functions.

36
Shifts of C and S functions
  • A rise in household wealth will increase C for
    every level of YD, so C shifts up.
  • A rise in average prices will lower the real
    wealth of households and so lower C for every
    level of YD, so C shifts down.

37
Example Alice and Sam
  • Question Alice and Sam are a typical two-income
    couple who live for ballroom dancing. Their
    combined salaries come to 1,400 per week after
    tax. They spend
  • 300 per week on rent,
  • 300 per week on car payments,
  • 200 per week on ballroom dancing functions and
  • 200 per week on everything else.
  • (a) Calculate their APC, APS, MPC and MPS.

38
Example Alice and Sam
  • Sam injures his back and is forced to take a
    lighter work-load, so their combined incomes drop
    to 1,000 per week. Due to the back injury,
    Alice and Sam are forced to stop their ballroom
    dancing, however their spending in the
    everything else category rises to 300.
  • (b) Calculate their APC, APS, MPC and MPS.
    Create graphs to show this information.

39
Consumption function
  • The consumption function relates the level of
    private household consumption of goods and
    services (C) to the level of aggregate income
    (Y).
  • We can represent the consumption function in
    three different and equivalent ways.
  • An mathematical equation
  • A graph
  • A table
  • For example the consumption function could be
  • C 100bn 0.5Y

40
Consumption function
  • We can represent this same function with a graph.

C
C(Y) 100bn 0.5Y
150bn
Slope is 0.5
100bn
The MPC is 0.5
Y
100bn
41
Consumption function
  • Or we can represent the same function with a
    table.
  • Three ways of represent-ing the same function.

Y C(Y) 100 0.5Y C
0 100 0.5 (0) 100
100 100 0.5 (100) 150
200 100 0.5 (200) 200
300 100 0.5 (300) 250
400 100 0.5 (400) 300
500 100 0.5 (500) 350
42
Exogenous variables
  • Exogenous variables are variables in a model that
    are determined outside the model itself, so
    they appear as constants.
  • For the aggregate expenditure model, we treat as
    exogenous
  • Investment (I)
  • Government consumption (G)
  • Taxes (T)
  • Net Exports (NX)

43
Aggregate expenditure
  • In a closed (no foreign trade) economy
  • AE C(Y) I G
  • In an open economy
  • AE C(Y) I G NX
  • Changes in a or the exogenous variables (I, G, T
    or NX) will shift the AE curve. A change in b
    will tilt the AE curve.
  • Equilibrium occurs when goods supply, Y, is equal
    to goods demand, AE.

44
Two sector model
  • Aggregate expenditure (AE) in the two sector
    model is composed of consumption (C) and
    investment (I).
  • AE C I
  • In this model, we treat I as exogenous, so it is
    a constant.
  • Lets use the same simple linear consumption
    function
  • C 100 0.5Y
  • I 100
  • AE C I 100 0.5Y 100 200 0.5Y

45
Aggregate expenditure function
  • This equation is a relationship between income
    (Y) and aggregate expenditure (AE).

AE 200 0.5Y
250bn
Slope is 0.5
200bn
Y
100bn
46
Aggregate expenditure function
Y C I AE
0 100 100 200
100 150 100 250
200 200 100 300
300 250 100 350
400 300 100 400
500 350 100 450
  • But we could also use the table form.

47
Equilibrium in two sector model
  • Equilibrium in a model is a situation of
    balance. In our AE model, equilibrium requires
    that demand for goods (AE) is equal to supply of
    goods (Y).
  • Y AE C I
  • For the equilibrium we are looking for the value
    of GDP, Y, such that goods demand and goods
    supply are equal.
  • In our two sector AE model that means that we can
    look up our AE table and find where AE Y.
  • The equilibrium value of Y will be our prediction
    of GDP for our AE model.

48
Equilibrium
  • The equilibrium value of GDP is 400bn.

Y C I AE
0 100 100 200
100 150 100 250
200 200 100 300
300 250 100 350
400 300 100 400
500 350 100 450
49
Equilibrium
  • We could accomplish the same by using our graph
    of the AE function.
  • The AE line shows us the level of goods demand
    for each value of Y.
  • The 45 degree line represents the value of Y or
    supply of goods.
  • Equilibrium will occur when the 45 degree line
    and the AE line cross. At the crossing, goods
    demand is equal to goods supply for that level of
    Y.

50
Equilibrium
  • The equilibrium value of Y is where the 45 degree
    line and the AE line cross. Y is at 400bn.

Y
AE 200 0.5Y
400
Y
400
51
Equilibrium
  • Finally, if you are comfortable with the
    mathematics, you can solve for the equilibrium
    value of Y using the equations
  • Y AE 200 0.5Y
  • Y 0.5Y 200
  • 0.5Y 200
  • Y 400
  • You arrive at the same answer no matter which way
    you use to derive it.

52
Autonomous expenditure
  • In our model we have two part of aggregate
    expenditure
  • AE 200bn 0.5Y
  • One part does not depend on the value of Y- the
    200bn. This portion is called autonomous
    expenditure.
  • The other part does depend on the value of Y- the
    0.5Y.
  • In our model part of autonomous expenditure is C
    and part is I.

53
Scenario Investment falls
Y C I AE
0 100 50 150
100 150 50 200
200 200 50 250
300 250 50 300
400 300 50 350
500 350 50 400
  • What happens if I drops from 100 to 50 perhaps
    because of uncertainty due to terrorism scares?
  • Equilibrium GDP drops to 300.

54
Scenario
  • But you could also find the same answer with some
    algebra
  • AE C I 100 0.5Y 50 150 0.5Y
  • Y AE 150 0.5Y
  • Y 0.5Y 150
  • 0.5Y 150
  • Y 300
  • Find the answer in the way you feel most
    comfortable.

55
Multiplier
  • So a 50bn drop in investment (or autonomous
    expenditure) leads to a 100bn drop in
    equilibrium GDP.
  • The ratio of the change in GDP over the change in
    autonomous expenditure is called the multiplier
  • Multiplier (Change in GDP)/(Change in I)

56
Expenditure multiplier
  • Imagine the government wishes to affect the
    economy. One tool available is government
    consumption, G, or government taxes, T. This is
    called fiscal policy.
  • Any change in G (?G) in our AE model will
    produce

57
Multiplier
  • If mpc0.75, then the multiplier is (1/0.25) or
    4, so 1 of new G will produce 4 of new Y.
  • Our multiplier is equal to 1/(1-MPC).
  • Since 0ltMPClt1, our multiplier will be greater
    than 1.
  • The larger is the MPC, the larger is our
    multiplier.

58
Three sector AE model
  • Now we make our model slightly more complicated
    by bringing in the government. The government
    has two effects on our model
  • The government raises tax revenues (T) by taxing
    household incomes.
  • The government purchases some goods and services
    for government consumption (G).
  • We treat the levels of T and G as exogenous to
    our AE model. Government policy determines what
    T and G will be, and policy is not affected by
    the equilibrium level of GDP.

59
Three sector model
  • Household consumption depended on household
    income, Y, in our two sector model.
  • In the three sector model, the income that
    households have available to spend or save is now
    income net of taxes, Y T. We call this amount
    disposable income, YD.
  • The consumption function will now depend on
    disposable income, not income.
  • C C(Y T) C(YD)

60
Three sector model
  • Our new aggregate expenditure function includes
    government purchases of goods and services, so we
    have
  • AE C I G
  • Lets assume we have the same linear consumption
    function as before, but now in disposable income
  • C 100 0.5 (Y T)
  • Let T G 50 and let I 100. We can follow
    the same steps as before to find our AE function
    and then to find equilibrium GDP.

61
Aggregate expenditure function
  • Our AE function is
  • AE C(Y T) I G
  • AE 100 0.5(Y 50) 100 50
  • AE 100 0.5Y 25 100 50
  • AE 225 0.5Y
  • We can also represent this as a table. Our C
    function with disposable income is
  • C 100 0.5(Y-50) 75 0.5Y

62
Table form
Y C 75 0.5Y I G AE
0 75 100 50 225
100 125 100 50 275
200 175 100 50 325
300 225 100 50 375
400 275 100 50 425
500 325 100 50 475
63
Equilibrium
  • If we want to find equilibrium GDP in our three
    sector model, we need to find the level of GDP,
    Y, for which goods demand (AE) is equal to goods
    supply (Y).
  • If we look at our table, we see that for an
    income level of Y of 400, AE is 425 which exceeds
    Y. At an income level of Y of 500, AE is 475
    which is less than Y.
  • We would guess that the equilibrium value of Y
    lies between 400 and 500.
  • We construct a new table of values of Y between
    400 and 500.

64
Equilibrium
Y C 75 0.5Y I G AE
400 275 100 50 425
425 287.5 100 50 437.5
450 300 100 50 450
475 312.5 100 50 462.5
500 325 100 50 475
65
Equilibrium
  • The equilibrium value of Y is 450.
  • We could find the answer with our equations
  • AE 225 0.5Y
  • Y AE 225 0.5Y
  • Y - 0.5Y 225
  • 0.5Y 225
  • Y 450

66
Scenario Investment falls
  • What happens if we have the same drop in
    investment in the three sector model? So I drops
    from 100 to 50?
  • Using our equations
  • AE 100 0.5(Y - T) I G
  • AE 75 0.5Y 50 50
  • AE 175 0.5Y
  • Solving for Y, we get
  • Y AE 175 0.5Y
  • Y 350
  • Our multiplier 100/50 2 as before.

67
Deriving aggregate demand
  • How do average prices affect demand for goods and
    services?
  • Real balances effect higher prices means our
    assets have less value so people are poorer and
    consume less.
  • Interest-rate effect higher prices drive up the
    demand for money and so drive up interest rates,
    at higher interest rates, investment falls (see
    later)
  • Foreign-purchases exports at higher Australian
    prices, foreign goods are cheaper, so net exports
    falls (see later)
  • As the average price level rises, demand for
    goods and services should fall, with all else
    held constant.

68
Deriving AD
  • So as P?, we expect
  • C? (real balances)
  • I? (interest rate)
  • NX? (foreign-purchases)
  • So as P?, we expect
  • AE C? I? G NX?
  • The AE curve shifts down.
  • Equilibrium Y falls.

69
Aggregate demand
  • We would like to have a relationship between the
    demand for goods and services and the price
    level. We call this the aggregate demand (AD)
    curve.
  • The AD curve is downward-sloping in aggregate
    price.

P0
P1
AD
Y0
Y1
Y
70
Shifts of the AD curve
  • Factors that affect the AE curve will affect the
    AD curve. For example, if household wealth rose,
    then C would increase for all levels of
    disposable income. Demand would be higher for
    all levels of prices, so the AD curve shifts to
    the right.
  • C household wealth, household expectations about
    the future
  • I interest rates, business expectation about the
    future, technology
  • G and T changes in fiscal policy
  • NX the currency exchange rate, change in output
    in foreign countries

71
AD and the multiplier
  • A change in I will shift the AE curve up. This
    will produce a shift to the right of the AD
    curve.
  • The shift in the AD curve will be the change in I
    times the multiplier.

72
Aggregate supply
  • The aggregate demand curve showed the
    relationship between goods demand and the average
    level of prices.
  • The aggregate supply (AS) curve shows the
    relationship between goods supply and the average
    level of prices.
  • By goods supply, we are thinking about all of the
    goods and services provided by all the producers
    in the economy.
  • How does the aggregate price level affect the
    aggregate level of goods and services supply?

73
Deriving the AS curve
  • We will differentiate between goods supply in the
    short-run (SR) and in the long-run (LR).
  • The crucial difference between the two time
    periods is that we will assume that nominal wages
    for employees are fixed in the SR. Workers
    money wages do not change in the SR. But
    workers wages are free to move in the LR.
  • So we will have two different AS curves- the SR
    AS and the LR AS curves.

74
Fixed nominal wages
  • How can we defend the assumption that wages are
    fixed in the SR?
  • All wages in a modern economy are set either via
    contracts between employers and employees or via
    a labour agreement between unions and employers.
  • These contracts specify well in advance (a few
    months to several years) what the wages of a
    worker will be in nominal terms.
  • These contracts are usually very difficult to
    change.

75
Supply of an individual firm
  • So what effect will this assumption of fixed
    wages have? To think about this, we will think
    about the supply of a small firm in our economy.
  • Intuition If the output price for a firm rises,
    but the cost of labour stays the same, a firm
    will want to increase profits by producing more
    output. But if the output price and the cost of
    labour both rise by the same amount, a firm will
    not increase output.

76
Deriving the SR AS curve
  • In the short-run (SR), since wages are fixed, a
    rise in P will have no affect on W, so individual
    firms will find it profitable to increase output.
  • As all firms are raising output, aggregate supply
    will increase in the SR if aggregate prices rise.
  • So the SR AS curve is upward-sloping in aggregate
    prices.

77
Deriving the LR AS curve
  • We assume that workers are interested in their
    real wages (wages relative to prices W/P).
  • If P rises, workers will demand a compensating W
    rise, so as to keep real wages the same as
    before.
  • In the LR, real wages are unchanged by changes in
    P, so output is not affected by changes in P.
  • The LR AS curve is vertical at the natural rate
    of output.

78
The LR AS curve
  • The LR AS curve is vertical, so long-run Y does
    not depend on prices.
  • The long-run Y is determined by
  • Labour skills
  • Capital efficiency
  • Technology
  • Labour market rules
  • And others

P
LR AS
Low U/E
High U/E
YLR
Y
79
Review Aggregate supply
  • There will be a short-run AS curve which is
    upward-sloping in prices.
  • The SR AS (or usually just AS) is used to model
    scenarios.
  • The long-run AS curve is vertical at the level of
    potential output, since wages will change
    proportionately to price changes.
  • The LR AS is used (mostly) to talk about
    unemployment.

80
Equilibrium
  • Equilibrium occurs at a price level where goods
    demand (AD) is equal to goods supply (SR AS).

P
AS
P0
AD
Y0
Y
81
Unemployment
LR AS
  • The gap between the natural rate of output and
    current output is called the recessionary gap.
  • The level of unemployment depends on the size of
    this gap.

P
AS
P0
Unemployment
AD
Y0
YLR
Y
82
Shift in AD (C? or G? or T? or I? or NX?)
83
Shift in AD
  • We start with an economy of 10tr and a price
    level of 110.
  • A change in autonomous expenditure causes the AE
    curve to shift from AE0 to AE1. We move to a new
    AD curve at AD1.
  • At the old price level of 110, AD gt AS by 2tr,
    so prices rise, pushing AD down and AS up until
    we reach out new equilibrium.
  • Our new equilibrium will have higher P and Y than
    when we started.

84
Shift in AD
85
Shift in AS (rise in oil prices)
AS1
  • A rise in oil prices raises the cost of
    production for all producers and shifts the SR AS
    curve up/to the left.
  • At the old prices, AD gt AS, so prices rise and
    output falls.

P
AS0
P1
P0
AD
Y1
Y0
Y
86
Business cycle
  • Over the business cycle, we will have periods of
    high output (booms) and periods of low output
    (recessions).
  • In booms, output is high and unemployment is low,
    while in recessions, output is low and
    unemployment is high.
  • The natural rate of unemployment is the level
    of unemployment in a normal period of the
    economy. This is achieved when output is at
    full-employment or the LR AS level.

87
A Boom in the Economy
LR AS
  • An economy in a boom is an economy with an output
    level higher than the natural rate of output.
  • Unemployment is below the natural rate in a boom.

P
AS
P0
AD
Y0
YLR
Y
88
A Recession
LR AS
  • An economy in a recession is an economy with an
    output level below the natural rate of output.
  • Unemployment is above the natural rate in a
    recession.

P
AS
P0
AD
Y0
YLR
Y
89
Sample AD-AS question
  • The small country of Speckonamap is in long-run
    equilibrium with its aggregate demand (AD) and
    short-run aggregate supply (AS) curves
    intersecting on the long-run aggregate supply
    curve (ASLR). The dot-com bubble in Speckonmaps
    industry bursts. Business investment drops.
  • a. Explain the short- and long-term consequences
    of this bursting bubble using the AD-AS diagram.
    Be as clear and complete as you can.

90
Sample AD-AS question
  • b. What policies could the government of
    Speckonamap pursue to counter the collapse of
    business investment? Think of two different ways
    that the government could shift the AD-AS curves.

91
Investment
  • Investment can refer to the purchase of new goods
    that are used for future production. Investment
    can come in the form of machines, buildings,
    roads or bridges. This is called physical
    capital.
  • Another type of investment is called human
    capital. This is investment in education,
    training and job skills.
  • Usually when we talk about investment, we mean
    investment in physical capital, but investment
    should include all forms of capital.

92
Investment decision-making
  • How to determine profitability of investment?
  • Example An investment involves the current cost
    of investment (I). The investment will pay off
    with some flow of expected future profits. The
    future stream of profits is R1 in one years
    time, R2 in two years time, up to Rn at the
    nth year when the investment ends.
  • Net Present Value (NPV) Present Value of Future
    Profits (PV) Investment (I)

93
Investment decision-making
  • What determines investment?
  • Businesses or individuals make an investment if
    they expect the investment to be profitable.
  • Imagine we have a small business owner who is
    faced with an investment decision.
  • The small business owner will make the investment
    as long as the investment is profitable.
  • How to determine profitability of investment?

94
Profitability of an investment
  • Example
  • An investment involves the current cost of
    investment (I).
  • The investment will pay off with some flow of
    expected future profits.
  • The future stream of profits is R1 in one years
    time, R2 in two years time, up to Rn at the
    nth year when the investment ends.
  • Imagine you are the business owner. How do we
    decide whether to make the investment? Can we
    simply add up the benefits (profits) and subtract
    the costs (investment)?
  • Profits today R1 R2 Rn I?
  • What is wrong with this calculation?

95
Present value concept
  • Imagine our rule about future values was simply
    to add future costs and benefits to costs and
    benefits today.
  • Scenario A friend offers you a deal
  • Give me 10 today, and I promise to give you 20
    in 1 years time.
  • If we subtract costs (10) from benefits (20),
    we get a positive value of 10. Does this seem
    like a sensible decision?
  • Scenario A friend offers you a deal
  • Give me 10 today, and I promise to give you 20
    in 100 years time.
  • If we subtract costs (10) from benefits (20),
    we get a positive value of 10. Does this seem
    like a sensible decision?

96
Present value concept
  • Not really. The problem is that a 1 today is
    not the same as a 1 in a years time or 100
    years time.
  • We can not directly add these 1s together since
    they are not the same things. We are adding
    apples and oranges.
  • We need a way of translating future 1s into 1s
    today, so that we can add the benefits and costs
    together.
  • The conversion is called present value.
  • In making the decision about our friends deal,
    we would compare 10 today to the present value
    of the 20 in a year or 100 years.

97
Present value concept
  • An investment is about giving up something today
    in order to get back something in the future.
  • So an investment decision will always involve
    comparing 1s today to 1s in the future.
  • Investment decisions will always involve present
    values. If we subtract the present value of
    future profits from costs today, we get net
    present value.
  • Net Present Value (NPV) Present Value of Future
    Profits (PV) Investment (I)

98
Net present value
  • The investment rule will be to invest if and only
    if
  • NPV 0
  • Or
  • Present Value of Future Profits (PV) Investment
    (I) 0

99
Interest rates
  • Interest rates are a general term for the
    percentage return on a dollar for a year
  • that you earn from banks for saving
  • that you pay banks for borrowing or investing
  • For example, the interest rate might be 10, so
    if you put 1 in the bank this year, it will
    become (1i) in one years time.
  • Or if you borrow 100 today, you will have to
    repay (1i)100 next year.

100
Interest Rates
101
Discounting future values
  • How do we place a value today on 1 in t years
    time?
  • This is called discounting the future value.
    One way to think about this question is to ask
  • How much would we have to put in the bank now to
    have 1 in t years time?
  • Money in the bank earns interest at the rate at
    the rate i, igt0. If I put 1 in the bank today,
    it will grow to be (1 i)1 in one years time,
    will grow to be (1i)(1i)1 (1i)2 in two
    years time and will grow to (1i)n in n years
    time.

102
Bank account
Year Value i.10
0 1 1
1 1(1i) 1.10
2 1(1i)(1i) 1.21
3 1(1i)3 1.33

n 1(1i)n (1.1)n
  • If we start with 1 in our bank account, what
    happens to our bank account over time?

103
How much is a future 1?
  • In order to have 1 next year, we would have to
    put x in today
  • 1 (1 i) x
  • x 1/(1i) lt 1
  • 1 next year is worth 1/(1 i) today. Since
    igt0, 1 next year is worth less than 1 today.
  • In order to have 1 in n years time, we would
    have to put x in today
  • x 1/(1i)n (1i)-n
  • 1 in n years time is worth 1/(1i)n lt 1 today.

104
PV of 1
Year i0.01 i0.05 i0.10 i0.20
0 1 1 1 1
1 0.99 0.95 0.91 0.83
2 0.98 0.91 0.83 0.69
3 0.97 0.86 0.75 0.58
10 0.91 0.61 0.39 0.16
n (1.01)-n (1.05)-n (1.10)-n (1.20)-n
105
Net present value
  • NPV R1/(1i) R2/(1 i)2 Rn/(1 i)n I
  • If NPV gt0, then go ahead and make the
    investment. If NPV lt 0, then the investment is
    not worthwhile.
  • As i rises, the PV of future profits will drop,
    so the NPV will fall. If we imagine that there
    are thousands of potential investments to be
    made, as i rises, fewer of these potential
    investments will be profitable, and so investment
    will fall.
  • We expect then that I falls as i rises.

106
Investment decision
  • Imagine we are the small business owner we were
    discussing before. We have a new project which
    we might invest in
  • An investment involves the current cost of
    investment (I).
  • The investment will pay off with some flow of
    expected future profits.
  • The future stream of profits is R1 in one years
    time, R2 in two years time, up to Rn at the
    nth year when the investment ends.

107
Investment decision
Year Benefit Cost PV
0 0 I -I
1 R1 0 R1/(1i)
2 R2 0 R2/(1i)2
3 R3 0 R3/(1i)3

n Rn 0 Rn/(1i)n
108
Net present value
  • The NPV of the investment is the sum of the
    values in the far-right column- the PVs.
  • NPV R1/(1i) R2/(1 i)2 Rn/(1 i)n I
  • If NPV 0, then go ahead and make the
    investment. If NPV lt 0, then the investment is
    not worthwhile.
  • Lets look at a more concrete example that we can
    put some numbers to.

109
Example of NPV
  • Example A small business in Bathurst that owns
    photo store is considering installing a
    state-of-the-art developing machine for digital
    photographs.
  • Cost 12,000 (after selling current machine)
  • Future benefits 2,000 per year in extra
    business every year for 10 year life-span of
    machine (assume benefits start next year)

110
Example of NPV
Year Benefit Cost PV
0 0 I -12,000
1 2,000 0 2,000/(1i)
2 2,000 0 2,000/(1i)2
3 2,000 0 2,000/(1i)3

10 2,000 0 2,000/(1i)10
111
Example of NPV
  • NPV -12,000 2,000/(1i) 2,000/(1i)2
    2,000/(1i)3 2,000/(1i)10
  • Our NPV then depends upon the interest rate, i,
    facing the small business.
  • For a small business, the relevant interest rate
    would be the rate that it cost raise the money,
    say by taking out a bank loan.
  • So the interest rate would be the bank small
    business loan rate.

112
Example of NPV
  • The NPV varies with the interest rate
  • At i0.05, NPV 3,443, so go ahead with
    investment.
  • At i0.08, NPV 1,420, so go ahead with
    investment.
  • At i0.10, NPV 289, so go ahead with
    investment.
  • At i0.12, NPV -700, so dont go ahead with
    the investment.
  • Somewhere between a 10 and a 12 interest rate,
    NPV 0. NPV lt 0 for all interest rates greater
    than 12.

113
Example of NPV
  • Another way of thinking about this problem is to
    ask Can I repay the loan and still make money?
  • The small business owner borrows 12,000 from the
    bank and uses the 2,000 in extra business each
    year to repay the loan.
  • Would the business owner repay the loan before
    the machine needs to be replaced?

114
Example of NPV- bank loan
Year 0.05 0.08 0.1 0.12
0 -12000 -12000 -12000 -12000
1 -10600 -10960 -11200 -11440
2 -9130 -9836.8 -10320 -10812.8
3 -7586.5 -8623.74 -9352 -10110.3
4 -5965.83 -7313.64 -8287.2 -9323.58
5 -4264.12 -5898.74 -7115.92 -8442.41
6 -2477.32 -4370.63 -5827.51 -7455.49
7 -601.19 -2720.28 -4410.26 -6350.15
8 1368.75 -937.91 -2851.29 -5112.17
9 3437.19 987.06 -1136.42 -3725.63
10 5609.05 3066.03 749.94 -2172.71
Present Value 3443.47 1420.16 289.13 -699.55
115
Example of a NPV- bank loan
  • So for interest rates of 10 and below, the bank
    loan is repaid before the machine wears out, so
    the investment is worthwhile.
  • For interest rates of 12 and above, the bank
    loan is not repaid by the time the machine needs
    to be replaced, so the investment is not
    worthwhile.
  • The bottom line shows that the remainder in the
    bank account at the end of 10 years is the NPV of
    the investment decision.
  • So another way to think of NPV is as the money
    left in an account at the end of a project.

116
Investment demand
  • Instead of thinking about a single small
    business, think of a whole economy of businesses
    and individuals making investment decisions.
  • Some of these investment decisions will be very
    good ones and some will be very poor ones. There
    is a whole range.
  • As i rises, the PV of future profits will drop,
    so the NPV will fall. If we imagine that there
    are thousands of potential investments to be
    made, as i rises, fewer of these potential
    investments will be profitable, and so investment
    will fall.

117
Investment demand
  • If we graphed the investment demand for goods and
    services (I) against interest rates, it would be
    downward-sloping in i. The higher is i, the
    lower is investment demand.
  • What can shift the I curve? Factors that affect
    current and expected future profitability of
    projects
  • New technology
  • Business expectations
  • Business taxes and regulation

118
Shifts in investment demand
  • Example An increase in business
    confidence/expectations raises the expected
    future profits for businesses.
  • At the same interest rates as before, since the
    Rs are higher, the NPVs of all investment
    projects will be higher.
  • The investment demand curve is shifted to the
    right. I is higher for all interest rates.

119
Uses of PV concept
  • Housing valuation We can use the PV concept to
    estimate what house prices should be.
  • What do you have when you own a home? You have
    the future housing services of that home plus the
    right to sell the home.
  • Value of housing services should be the price
    people pay to rent an equivalent home. Rent is
    the price of a week of housing services.
  • Lets say your home rents for 250 per week.

120
Housing valuation
  • If you stayed in your home for 50 years, your
    house is worth the PV of 50 years of 52 weekly
    250 payments plus any sale value at 50 years.
    How do we calculate the PV of such a long stream
    of numbers?
  • Trick For very long streams, the sum
  • PV (250 x 52) (250 x 52)/(1i)
  • Is very close to
  • PV (250 x 52) / i 13,000 / i

121
Housing valuation
  • So we get the house values
  • At i0.02, PV House 650,000
  • At i0.03, PV House 433,000
  • At i0.05, PV House 260,000
  • At i0.06, PV House 217,000
  • At i0.07, PV House 186,000
  • At a house price above this price, you are better
    off selling your house and renting for 50 years.
    At a house price below this price, you are better
    off owning a house.

122
Housing valuation
  • You can also see how sensitive house prices are
    to the interest rate. When i rose from 6 to 7,
    the value of the house dropped 31,000.
  • You can see why home owners care so much about
    the home loans rates.
  • But what about the resale price at 50 years?
  • The PV of the house sale in 50 years time is
    (Sale Price) / (1i)50, which for most values of
    i is going to be a very small number- 8 of Sale
    Price at 5 interest and 3 of Sale Price at 7
    interest.

123
Housing price bubbles
  • Sometimes the price of housing can vary from this
    PV of housing services price. Some analysts
    argue that todays housing prices is one case-
    these periods are called bubbles.
  • Example At 6 interest rates our house was
    worth 217,000. Lets say Sam bought the house
    for 300,000 in order to sell the house one year
    from now.
  • In order to be able to repay the 300,000, Sam
    has to gain 18,000 (6 of 300,000) by holding
    the house for a year.

124
Housing price bubbles
  • Since Sam gets 13,000 worth of housing services
    from the house, the value of the house has to
    rise 5,000 to 305,000 in next years sale for a
    total gain of 18,000.
  • Even though the house is unchanged, the
    overpayment for the house has to rise- the
    house is still only worth 217,000 in housing
    services- but it now sells for 305,000.
  • So in a bubble, if people are overpaying for a
    house, the overpayment has to keep rising.
    Eventually people realize that the house only
    generates 217,000 in services.

125
Housing price bubbles
  • Example In Holland in 1636, the price of some
    rare and exotic tulip bulbs rose to the
    equivalent of a price of an expensive house.
    People paid that much in plans to resell at even
    higher prices.
  • In 1637, prices for tulips crashed and by 1639,
    tulip bulbs were selling for 1/200th of the peak
    prices.
  • Bubbles tend to crash fast and dramatically.

126
Example Bond Valuation
  • You can save money at the bank and earn a 10
    yearly return on your savings. What is the most
    you would be willing to pay for (include your
    calculations and explain carefully)
  • a. a promise of a 1 in one years time (assume
    that this promise will not be broken)

127
Example question
  • b. a 10 year 100 savings bond (the bond will pay
    you 100 in the year 2015, where 2015 is known as
    the maturity date) and do a graph of the value
    of the 10 year 100 maturity in 2015 savings bond
    as we get closer to the maturity date and

128
Example question
  • c. a 10 year 100 savings bond that also pays you
    5 per year for every year that you hold the bond
    (including the 10th year).

129
Resources
  • There are many resources available to you. Often
    students hurt themselves by not taking advantage
    of the resources they have.
  • Books There are plenty of macroeconomics
    principles books. If you dont understand
    Jackson and McIvers coverage, get to a library
    and read a different textbook. There is also a
    study guide by Bredon and Curnow referenced in
    the subject outline.
  • Online There is an enormous amount of material
    on the Web. Just use a search engine and look
    around.

130
Resources
  • Forum Get into a habit of reading the CSU forums
    once a week. Post questions on the forum and
    join in the discussion.
  • Official websites Have a look at the websites
    for government agencies like the Reserve Bank of
    Australia or the Australian Bureau of Statistics.
  • CSU help Student Services at CSU has a lot of
    help it can provide students with problems- look
    at http//www.csu.edu.au/division/studserv/.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com