Increasing Returns and Economic Efficiency - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 43
About This Presentation
Title:

Increasing Returns and Economic Efficiency

Description:

B. Pecuniary external effects may have real efficiency implications ... the traditional analysis showing the absence of inefficiency of pecuniary ext. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:40
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 44
Provided by: ser75
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Increasing Returns and Economic Efficiency


1
Increasing Returns and Economic Efficiency
2
More Seriously
  • Learning costs, indivisibilities giving rise to
    sizable fixed costs. Information and knowledge in
    production makes IR prevalent (Wilson 1975,
    Radner Stiglitz 1984, Arrow 1995).
  • Empirical evidence for IR (Ades Glaeser 1999,
    Antweiler Trefler 2002).

3
IR and Economic Analysis
  • Largely ignored in the core, esp. in GE analysis.
  • Frequently discussed in IO, development
    economics, international trade.
  • Surveys Yang S. Ng (1998) Yang (2001), Cheng
    Yang (2003).
  • Reading G. Sun (forthcoming).

4
One clear conclusion is that there are many
important areas of economics in which the
recognition of increasing returns makes a big
difference, and changes the established wisdom
significantly. we have not yet reached the point
of diminishing returns in the study of increasing
returns there is a long way to go, and the
results of the work yet to be completed will be
interesting (Geoffrey Heal, 1999).
5
Different Types of IR
  • IR at the firm level, economies of scale.
  • IR at the industry level due to external
    economies (Marshall 1920, Chipman 1970, Romer
    1986).
  • IR at the economy level due to economies of
    specialization (ES)/division of labour (DL)
    (Smith, Young, Rosen, Yang, Buchanan).
  • IR at the world level (Ethier 1979, Chandra et
    al. 2002).

6
Different Analytical Sources of IR
  • Property of the production function
    indivisibilities.
  • External economies due to knowledge transmission,
    economies internal to another industry, etc.
  • Higher productivity from the use of more
    intermediate inputs (Ethier 1979, 1982).
  • ES at the individual level (Smith, Yang).

7
Many Traditional Results Have to be Drastically
Revised
  • Significant IR at the firm level is inconsistent
    with perfect competition.
  • Perfect competition also inconsistent with the
    virtually omnipresent product differentiation.
  • But allowing for non-perfect competition play
    havocs to many traditional results.

8
A.Neutrality of money may not hold
  • Even no time lags, money illusion, and other
    frictions, just non-perfect competition may make
    a change in nominal aggregate demand affect
    either the price level (the monetarist case) or
    the real output (the Keynesian case).
  • Expectation wonderland (outcome depends on
    expectation which will be self-fulfilling) and
    cumulative expansion/contraction are also
    possible, partly explaining some real-world
    phenomena like business cycles, importance of
    confidence, and difficulties of prediction (Ng
    1977, 1980, 1986, 1992, 1998, 1999 Ng Wu
    2002).

9
In the non-traditional cases, there exists an
interfirm macroeconomic externality where the
expansion by each firm benefits other firms apart
from the familiar income multiplier effects. This
is an area where welfare economics,
macroeconomics and its micro-foundation
intersect, an area still not adequately studied.
10
The crux of the difference
  • Demand Side A horizontal demand curve cannot
    shift left or right, only up or down. But an
    upward shift means an increase in price. With no
    time lags, money illusion, this leads to a
    similar shift in MC.
  • Supply Side MC upward-sloping under perfect
    competition may be horizontal or downward
    sloping (esp. with IR) under non-perfect
    competition.

11
The analysis is based on a representative firm
but it takes account of the influence of macro
variables and the interaction (including
infinite number of feedback loops) with the
rest of the economy, using a simplified
general-equilibrium method.
12
Moreover, a fully general-equilibrium analysis is
used to show
  • (1) for any (exogenous) change in cost or demand,
    there exists a hypothetical representative firm
    whose response accurately represents that of the
    whole economy in aggregate output and average
    price
  • (2) a representative firm defined by a simple
    weighted average can be used as a good
    approximation of the whole economy to any
    economy-wide change in demand and/or costs that
    does not result in drastic inter-firm changes.
    (See Ng 1986, App. 3I.)

13
B. Pecuniary external effects may have real
efficiency implications
  • Even where the supply/demand analysis is still
    applicable, if the supply curve is downward
    sloping due to whatever source of IR, the
    traditional analysis showing the absence of
    inefficiency of pecuniary ext. effects is no
    longer valid.

14
C. Market equilibrium no longer Pareto Optimal
  • Well-known that IR may give rise to efficiency
    problems (e.g. Arrow 1987, 2000, Guesnerie 1975,
    Heal 1999, Quinzii 1992, Villar 1996).
  • Pigou (1920) advocated tax/subsidy on goods with
    up/downward sloping supply curves. Further
    discussion (reprinted in AEA 1952) revealed
    problems. Pigous example a non-congested, wide
    but uneven road and a congested, narrow but good
    road, to illustrate the over-use of the narrow
    road with increasing costs. Knight (1924)
    failure of pricing the congested road. With
    optimal pricing, no overuse.

15
  • Dixit Stiglitz (1977) show that no general
    conclusion can be made.
  • The more specific models of Heal (1980, 1999)
    show that the combination of imperfection
    competition and IR leads to the over-serving of
    large markets and under-serving of small markets.
  • See also Spence 1976 on optimal product variety.

16
  • Even abstracting from monopolistic output
    restriction by assuming AC-pricing from
    contestability, Section 2 shows that goods with
    higher degrees of IR are under-expanded.
  • Subsidies on goods with (high degrees of) IR
    financed by taxes on goods with non and lower IR
    may increase efficiency.
  • But may open up a flood-gate of rent-seeking
    activities. Perhaps it is optimal to continue to
    pretend that IR do not exist. Ha!
  • Unlikely true for all issues otherwise,
    policies like encouraging the development of the
    great western region in China does not make
    sense.

17
Existence of AC-Pricing Equilibria with IR
  • Theorem 1 (Brown-Heal generalized) A
    productively efficient AC-pricing equilibrium
    exists.
  • Proof While the production possibility set need
    not be convex, the production possibility
    frontier (super-surface) is topologically
    equivalent to a compact and convex set. From
    Brouwers fixed point theorem, any continuous
    mapping of a set homeomorphic to a compact and
    convex set onto itself possess a fixed point.
    Thus, any continuous mapping of the PPF has a
    fixed point.

18
  • Consider the following continuous mapping ? of
    PPF into PPF (G1, , Gg)0 ? (W1/WR, , WR-1/WR)0
    (P1, , PG)0 ? (Gd1, , Gdg)1 ? (G1, , Gg)2,
    where
  • (i) (G1, , Gg)0 is an arbitrary point on the
    PPF.
  • (ii) (W1/WR, , WR-1/WR)0 is the set of relative
    resource prices determined by the common (to all
    firms using the same pair of resources) marginal
    rates of technical substitution as specified in
    (2.7) above at the point Gg(R1g, , RRg) G0g g
    1, , G, i.e. the same point as (G1, , Gg)0.

19
  • (iii) (P1, , PG)0 product prices at AC, i.e.
    P0g Cg(W1, , WR, Gg)/Gg g 1, , G, at the
    given production levels given by (G1, , Gg)0.
  • (iv) (Gd1, , Gdg)1 is the market demand for the
    various goods, i.e. Gdg G1g , GIg g 1, ,
    G, where each Gig is the individual
    utility-maximization quantity of the g good
    demanded by individual i at the set of product
    prices (P1, , PG)0 and resource prices (W1/WR,
    , WR-1/WR)0.
  • (v) (G1, , Gg)2 is the intersection of the ray
    through the point (Gd1, , Gdg)1 and the PPF.

20
  • Since the mapping ? is continuous and the PPF is
    homeopmorphic to a compact and convex set, the
    mapping has a fixed point which is denoted as
    (G1, , Gg). At this fixed point, (G1, , Gg)0
    (Gd1, , Gdg)1 (G1, , Gg)2 (G1, , Gg).
    Hence, demand for goods (G1, , Gg)1 equals
    supply (G1, , Gg)0 at the product prices (P1, ,
    PG), the AC of producing the various goods at
    (G1, , Gg)0. The equilibrium relative resource
    prices (W1/WR, , WR-1/WR) is the common MRTS
    specified in (2.7). This production point gives
    equilibrium values of resource demand Rrg r 1,
    , R g 1, , G satisfying (2.11). Finally, the
    individual demands for products Gig i 1, , I
    g 1, , G total to satisfy (2.10). Since the
    production point is on the PPF, it is
    productively efficient. This completes the proof.

21
Efficiency of Encouraging Goods with High Degrees
of IR
  • (3.1) Pg Ag for all good g,
  • Define the (local) degree of IR
  • (3.2) Ig ? - (?Ag/?Gg)Gg/Ag
  • (3.5) Uig/Uih Pg/Ph (Utility max.)
  • Pareto optimality Uig/Uih Fg/Fh Mg/Mh
  • From (3.1) and (3.5), a market equilibrium
  • (3.8) Uig/Uih Ag/Ah
  • (3.9) Ig ? - (?Ag/?Gg)Gg/Ag 1 Mg/Ag
  • (3.10) Ig gt Ih iff Ag/Ah gt Mg/Mh.

22
  • From (3.8) and (3.10) For any market equilibrium
    P (3.11) MRSgh gt Mg/Mh iff Ig gt Ih.
  • The (absolute) slope of PPF in the g/h plane
    equals Mg/Mh (with good g on the horizontal
    axis).
  • If good g has a higher degree of IR than good h,
    the market-equilibrium MRSgh gt slope of PPF.
  • A movement down the (downward-sloping) PPF
    involving more good g and less good h must reach
    a higher indifference curve/surface.
  • Theorem 2A At an AC-pricing market equilibrium,
    if the degree of IR for good g is larger than
    that for good h, a point of higher efficiency
    (Pareto-superior) could be reached by increasing
    good g and decreasing h.

23
  • Next, a cost-benefit analysis is used to show
  • Theorem 2B At an AC-pricing market equilibrium,
    if the production/consumption of a good with a
    lower IR is decreased to allow for a
    corresponding increase in the production/consumpti
    on of another good with a higher IR, holding the
    consumption/production of other goods unchanged,
    the aggregate net benefits of the change is
    positive.
  • A specific example confirms the above results.
  • But, Information rent-seeking.

24
Joint paper with D.S. Zhang
  • The analysis of economies of specialization at
    the individual level by Yang Shi (1992) and
    Yang Ng (1993) is combined with the Dixit
    Stiglitz (1977) analysis of monopolistic-competiti
    ve firms to show that, even if both the home and
    the market sectors have IR and there are no
    pre-existing taxes, it is still efficient to tax
    the home sector to finance a subsidy on the
    market sector to offset the under-production of
    the latter due to the failure of price-taking
    consumers to take account of the effects of
    higher consumption in reducing the average costs
    and hence prices, through IR or the publicness
    nature of fixed costs.
  • But offset by environmental concerns.

25
Average-cost pricing, increasing returns, and
optimal output in a model with home and market
production
  • Yew-Kwang NgDept. of Economics, Monash
    University
  • Dingsheng Zhang
  • Dept. of Economics, Monash University
  • Institute for Advanced Economic Studies, Wuhan
    University

26
The Model
  • Consider an economy with M identical consumers.
    Each of them has the following decision problem
    for consumption, working, and home production.
  • Max
  • s.t.

27
The above optimization problem gives the
following solutions
28
  • We assume that the market structure is
    monopolistic competition. The production function
    of good r is
  • The first-order condition for the monopolist to
    maximize profit with respect to output level or
    price implies that

29
The general equilibrium values of the various
variables are
30
Comparative statics analysis
31
(No Transcript)
32
(No Transcript)
33
Equilibrium utility value
34
To analyse the welfare properties, we introduce
the government to the model
  • Assume that the tax rate of per unit home
  • labor is , and then consumers problem is
  • S.t.

35
  • In addition, denoting the subsidy rate per unit
    of market product as , the zero-profit
    condition for each firm is
  • Governments budget constrain is



36
we can get the equilibrium level of utility as
37
  • where

38
  • The effect of a change in tax rate on the
    equilibrium value of utility with respect to the
    tax rate, and with the subsidy rate at whatever
    level that is allowed by the government budget
    constraint as varies, evaluated at ,
    is given by

39
  • This means that, starting from the original
    position without any tax/subsidy, a tax on home
    production which finances for a subsidy on market
    production increases utility, ignoring
    administrative costs and any possible side
    effects, such as rent-seeking activities
    triggered by the subsidy. Since all firms just
    break-even in equilibrium, we may base our
    welfare comparisons simply on the utility levels
    alone. We thus have,

40
  • Proposition 1 In our model with both home and
    market production under the conditions of
    increasing returns and average-cost pricing, a
    subsidy, if not excessive, on market production
    financed by a tax on home production improves
    efficiency even if the initial position involves
    no tax distortion, ignoring administrative costs
    and any possible side effects.

41
  • We extend the above model to allow for different
    sectors of market goods that may have different
    degrees of elasticity of substitution and
    different degrees of increasing returns (through
    different values of the fixed cost and marginal
    cost), we have similar results.

42
  • Proposition 2 In our model with both home and
    market production under the conditions of
    increasing returns and average-cost pricing with
    two sectors of different fixed costs,
    elasticities of substitution, and degree of
    importance in preference, it is efficient to tax
    the sector with lower fixed costs, higher
    elasticity of substitution and/or higher degree
    of importance in preference and subsidize the
    other.

43
Concluding Remarks
  • Our conclusions applicability to the real
    economy is subject to important qualifications.
    First, the government may not have the
    information to differentiate which goods should
    be taxed (and by how much) and which subsidized.
    Secondly, we have not considered other factors
    (including rent seeking) causing imperfect
    efficiency in the real economy.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com