Measuring Preferences for Redistribution and Fairness: An Experimental Approach - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 65
About This Presentation
Title:

Measuring Preferences for Redistribution and Fairness: An Experimental Approach

Description:

... made both as a disinterested observer, as an interested party ... Part 1 'Disinterested Observer' Condition ... Disinterested Observer' Demand for Equality ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:83
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 66
Provided by: r5107
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Measuring Preferences for Redistribution and Fairness: An Experimental Approach


1
Measuring Preferences for Redistribution and
Fairness An Experimental Approach
Ruben Durante Louis Putterman Brown
University
2
Stylized Facts
  • Luxembourg income survey data for OECD countries
    shows post-tax-and-transfer income share of
    bottom 40 is 14.7 percentage points above their
    pre-tax-and-transfer share (Milanovic, 2000)
  • Even in the U.S. the post-tax income shares of
    the bottom 40 is 7.8 higher than the pre-tax.
  • There are considerable differences across
    countries.

3
Big Questions
  • Why do we observe redistribution in democracies?
  • Why dont we observe more of it?
  • Why does the amount of redistribution vary among
    countries?
  • These questions motivate our study, but we try to
    address more specific subsidiary questions.

4
  • To know what determines the amount of
    redistribution, we need to know what accounts for
    redistribution in the first place.

5
Possible reasons for redistribution
  • Simple self-interest (the poor and middle class
    vote to redistribute from the rich).
  • Insurance motive (all risk-averse people may
    favor a system of social insurance)
  • Desire to reduce inequality
  • a. out of fear of social instability
  • b. out of social preference (inequality
  • aversion)

6
Possible limits on redistribution
  • Concern for negative impact on incentives, other
    dead weight losses.
  • Belief that inequalities are justly earned.
  • Disproportionate political influence of the rich.

7
main goal of our experiment is to investigate
relative importance of
  • Simple self-interest (the poor and middle class
    vote to redistribute from the rich).
  • Insurance motive (all risk-averse people favor a
    system of social insurance)
  • Desire to reduce inequality
  • (a. out of fear of social instability)
  • b. out of social preference (inequality
  • aversion, fairness preference)

8
we also obtain evidence on two of the limiting
factors
  • 1. Concern for negative impact on incentives,
    other dead weight losses (although theres no
    production or investment in the experiment, we
    can study concerns over exogenous changes in size
    of the pie)
  • 2. Belief that inequalities are justly earned.
  • (3. Disproportionate political influence of the
    rich not considered)

9
the experimental literature
  • There are many experiments bearing on fairness
    and other distributive preferences (e.g.,
    dictator games, ultimatum games, trust games,
    moonlighting games, Charness Rabins simple
    games, etc.) but usually these involve only two
    or three subjects interacting and have no
    suggestion or reference to the macro/political
    issue of redistribution in society.

10
experiments to measurepreferences for societal
income equalization
  • At least half of these (e.g., Amiel and Cowell)
    elicit preferences survey style, rather than in a
    manner that determines actual payoffs.
  • Others (Beck Beckman, Formby Smith Ackert,
    Martinez-Vasquez Rider) use real payoffs but
    lack one or more elements of our experiment, such
    as

11
  • - the group of affected individuals is large (we
    use group size 20 a dictator)
  • - decisions are made both as a disinterested
    observer, as an interested party under
    uncertainty, and as an interested party after
    resolution of uncertainty about own income
  • - decisions are made with respect to initial
    incomes determined both arbitrarily and in
    earned income conditions
  • - the variation in pre-tax incomes is very large
    (from max of 100 to min of 0.11)

12
  • - decisions are made with both different dead
    weight losses and with different private costs to
    the dictator, to study demand (willingness to
    pay)
  • - Unlike Frohlich and Oppenheimer and others, we
    dont explicitly ask subjects to think about
    their fairness or redistributive beliefs (until
    the debriefing), but we provide one mild framing
    cue (our pre-tax income distribution mimics that
    of income 5-percentiles in the U.S., and we tell
    our subjects that this is so).

13
tax scheme
  • The pre-tax-and-transfer distribution of income
    can be modified by a proportionate tax of 0, 0.1,
    0.2, 0.9, 1.0, with the tax proceeds (or the
    proceeds minus an exogenously imposed dead weight
    loss) redistributed equally among the twenty
    affected subjects.

14
  • We use a strategy-type method in which every
    subject potentially dictates the degree of
    redistributive taxation under each condition, so
    as
  • - to maximize the amount of data generated
  • - to avoid strategic voting issues

15
Why care what determines desires for
redistribution?
  • Normative relevance
  • If widespread support for a more equal income
    distribution exists, then redistributive taxation
    at reasonable cost unambiguously improves social
    welfare. If redistribution serves the selfish
    interest of some but not others, we need
    interpersonal comparability of welfare to make
    social welfare evaluations.
  • Positive relevance
  • Understanding to what extent redistribution is
    due to preferences for equality as opposed to
    other factors may help identifying the
    determinants of support for redistributive
    programs in society, and to understand why the
    level of redistribution differs significantly
    among countries.

16
Experimental Design
Two or three sets of decisions are made by each
subject in each session
  • Part 1 Disinterested Observer Condition
  • Each participant is asked to choose a tax rate to
    be applied to the pre-tax earnings distribution
    among the other 20 participants. At the end of
    the session one person, the decisive
    individual, is randomly selected to determine
    the actual degree of redistribution.

The earning of the D.I. is randomly selected from
the interval (19.80 21.80).
Purpose Evaluate participants redistributive
choices when self-interest is absent (or largely
so). Keep D.I.s identity secret.
17
Experiment Design (Cont.)
  • Part 2. Choice with Personal Stake Uncertainty
  • The setup is the same as in Exp. 1.
  • However, in this case the base earning of the
    decisive individual is determined in the same way
    as those of the other participants. The tax rate
    chosen by the decisive individual applies to
    everyones earning, including the D.I.s.

Purpose Analyze participants redistributive
choices when self-interest but also uncertainty
are present (the usual voting situation).
18
Experiment Design (Cont.)
  • Part 3. Choice with Personal Stake, Certainty
  • Subjects get to reconsider their tax choices in
    Part 2 after learning their exact income rankings.

Purpose Analyze participants redistributive
choices when self-interest is present and
uncertainty is resolved.
19
Pre-tax Earning Distribution
The pre-tax earnings of the twenty participants
are distributed proportionally to the pre-tax
income in the United States in 2000, by
5-percentiles.
20
Pre-tax Earnings Determination
  • How is assignment of subjects pre-tax earnings
    ranks determined? Four possibilities
  • Randomly
  • Based on home area average income, from ZIP code
    or country (Where From WF)
  • Based on performance in a game of skill (adapted
    version of Tetris)
  • Based on performance on a general knowledge Quiz

Purpose Analyze differences in agents attitude
toward redistribution for different determinants
of income inequality (i.e. luck, parental wealth,
ability, effort).
21
Taxes and Redistribution
  • Twenty participants pre-tax earning (xi) are
    taxed at a rate t and the proceedings are equally
    distributed among all agents. The post-tax
    pay-off for an affected subject is
  • yi (1 - t ) xi 1/20 (1 - e) (?i t xi) , ? i ?
    iD

Efficiency Loss (e) Proportion of the tax
revenue lost to redistribution (possible values
0, 12.5 25).
22
Tax cost versus efficiency loss
  • Tax cost is charged to the D.I. (dictator) only
    it is 0, 25 cents, 50 cents, and 1 dollar per 10
    worth of tax, varying across experiment sessions.
  • Tax cost affects the D.I. directly and thus lets
    us gauge her WTP for more equality.
  • Efficiency loss doesnt affect the D.I. in Part 1
    unless she cares about the sum of others
    earnings (as in Charness-Rabin 02).

23
Sequence of the Session
  • Part 1 - Instructions
  • Part 1 - Comprehension test
  • Part 1 - Decision stage
  • Part 2 - Instructions
  • Part 2 - Comprehension test
  • Part 2 - Pre decision stage (forecast)
  • Part 2 - Decision stage
  • Quiz
  • Tetris training
  • Tetris game
  • Selection of part paid-off on (Part 1 or Part 2)

24
Sequence of the Session (Cont.)
  • if Part 2 is selected
  • Provisional earning summary to each subject
  • Part 3 Tax Revisions possible
  • Method Determination (Random, WF, Quiz, or
    Tetris)
  • Risk aversion test
  • Decisive individual drawing
  • Final earnings summary
  • Exit survey
  • Background questions
  • Political inclination / ideology
  • Socio-economic status
  • General attitude toward equality and
    redistribution

25
Subject Pool(s)
  • We focus on 16 sessions with 336 Brown University
    undergraduates (21 per session) studying in every
    subject area.
  • 55 adult non-student subjects were recruited to 4
    other sessions not discussed, but generating
    similar results.

26
Sessions by Tax Cost and Efficiency Loss
of participants in parenthesis
27
Part 1Disinterested Observer
28
Demand for Equality
  • Although self-interested dictators should always
    select t 0 when tax cost gt 0, more than 75
    prefer a positive tax (prefer some
    redistribution), and even when tax cost 1 per
    10, 70 prefer some redistribution.

29
Preferences for Equality
  • Prediction When tax cost gt 0 we would expect t
    0

Mean Tax Rate 41.4
Mean Tax Rate 33.7
30
Responsiveness to Cost
  • Cross subject comparison shows some
    responsiveness to tax cost the higher the cost
    to the D.I., the less redistribution is demanded.

31
Tax Cost and Willingness to Pay
32
Responsiveness to dead-weight loss
  • Cross subject comparison shows that the larger
    the fraction of taxed output that is lost to
    inefficiency/leakage, the smaller the demand for
    redistribution.

33
Equality-Efficiency Trade-off
34
Demand for redistributionand the source of
inequality
  • Within-subject comparisons show that many
    subjects demand more redistribution when
    inequalities are arbitrary (random and where
    from methods) than when inequalities are earned
    (quiz and Tetris methods).

35
Tax choices differ significantlyacross methods.
36
  • However, the tendency to distinguish between
    inequalities of different origin
  • is linked to gender
  • males distinguish strongly,
  • females almost not at all.
  • Most of the difference between male and female
    tax preferences is due to different preferences
    under the earned methods.

37
(No Transcript)
38
These and other findingsare supported by
multivariate regressions, including Tobit.
  • Demand for redistribution varies
  • negatively with cost to the D.I.
  • negatively with dead weight loss
  • negatively with earned sources of inequality
    (quiz and Tetris)
  • positively with female gender
  • 5. positively with more liberal political
    philosophy

39
  • 6. positively with professed preference for
    equality.
  • 7. negatively with number of economics courses
    taken.
  • 8. positively with measured risk aversion
  • 9. negatively with family income

40
(No Transcript)
41
  • The impact of the source of income inequality,
    and the fact that gender differences are mainly
    due to different reactions to this, are shown in
    the following set of regressions.

42
(No Transcript)
43
PART 2Interested Decision-Maker
44
  • Recall that in Part 2,
  • - the D.I.s tax choice determines the degree of
    redistribution of the pre-tax earnings of 20
    subjects including him/herself.
  • - self-interest dictates choosing high (low) tax
    if you think youll rank near bottom (top)
  • - D.I. has not yet played Tetris or taken the
    quiz . . . decision-making under uncertainty
  • - decision in random condition is like
    Harsanyis choice behind veil of ignorance

45
  • - D.I.s earnings are directly affected by both
    tax cost and efficiency loss

46
Results in brief
  • Overall distribution of tax choices is very
    similar to that in Part 1
  • But self-interest contributes importantly to
    individuals choices where they have guesses
    about their pre-tax income ranks.
  • For Tetris, Quiz, and Where From
  • ? factors used in Part 1 regressions explain 13
    of variance in tax choices
  • ? own expected rank increases explained variance
    to 31, hence adds 18 to explained variance
    (R-Squared).

47
(No Transcript)
48
  • Interestingly, subjects expected own-income
    ranks for Where From, Quiz, and Tetris incomes
    also help to predict their Part 1 tax
    choicesalthough the addition to explained
    variance is lower than in Part 2.
  • Since subjects did not even know what the Part 2
    treatment would be when making Part 1 choices,
    the explanation is probably that subjects
    identify with people like themselves when
    choosing t (e.g., if I think Id do badly on
    Tetris, Id want the D.I. to select a high tax,
    so this is what I do as D.I., though it doesnt
    affect me personally).

49
  • In Part 2 like Part 1, males prefer more
    redistribution under Where From than under Quiz
    and Tetris, while females prefer similarly high
    redistribution under all three methods.

50
females
males
51
Random Pre-tax Incomes
  • Tax choices under random incomes (veil of
    ignorance) in Part 2 are significantly higher
    than in Part 1average 54.6 versus
    49.3consistent with self-interest and
    risk-aversion.
  • The next regression studies tax choice with
    random pre-tax incomes in both Part 1 and Part 2.

52
(No Transcript)
53
  • The regressions show that being more risk averse
    and being involving (being in Part 2) raise
    chosen t, but counter-intuitively the interaction
    between these two variables is insignificant and
    doesnt raise explained variance.

54
Average Part 2 Tax for All 4 Methods
55
Part 3 involved tax choice with certainty
about own rank
  • Included only for the 7 of 16 sessions in which
    Part 2 (involved) payoffs were chosen by coin
    toss
  • This helps keep D.I.s identity secret ex post.
  • Thus made by 147 subjects, 588 decisions (t for
    each of 4 methods x 147).

56
most decisions were fullyconsistent with
self-interest
  • After resolution of uncertainty about own rank,
    payoff maximization requires selecting t 0 or t
    100 (depending also on tax cost and dead
    weight loss)
  • About 66 of decisions were for own payoff
    maximizing tax rate.
  • There are slightly more deviations from a
    payoff-maximizing tax of 0 (toward more equality)
    than from a payoff-maximizing tax of 100 (toward
    less equality), but the difference is slight.

57
  • The cost of deviating varies depending on rank
  • For example, for subject with highest pre-tax
    income, each 10 of redistribution represents a
    personal sacrifice of about 8 not counting the
    regular tax cost and any dead weight loss. For
    subjects near cut-off rank, personal sacrifice is
    well under 1 per 10 when tax cost is small.
  • ? Calculating the individual cost of deviating
    by rank, factoring in tax cost and dead weight
    loss, we find deviations negatively related to
    this cost. (We plan to carry out an integrated
    analysis of response to tax cost using Part 3 and
    Part 1 together, hence covering wider range of
    costs.)

58
  • We analyze separately decisions of subjects
    whose income-maximizing tax choice is 0, then
    those whose income-maximizing tax choice is 100.
  • (Observations are by subject-and-method.)

59
Deviations from income-maximizing tax of 0
  • A quadratic specification with cost of deviation
    alone can explain 20 of the size of deviations
    (including 0 deviations).
  • Adding Part 1 tax choice (reflecting pure
    preference for equality) or explanatory variables
    including political philosophy can explain an
    addition 4 to 6 of the variance.

60
(No Transcript)
61
Deviations from income-maximizing tax of 100
  • This allows expression of preference for
    inequality under some conditions.
  • The quadratic personal cost specification
    explains only 0.3 of these deviations.
  • Adding Part 1 tax choice raises R-squared to 4.
    Part 1 tax choice is significant at the 1 level
    in this regression people who choose lower taxes
    for the income-determination method in question
    in Part 1 also choose lower taxes in Part
    3suggesting that they forego some earnings gain
    in support of their belief about just
    inequalities (e.g., right to earn more if did
    better on Quiz).

62

63
Provisional Conclusions
  • Most subjects are willing to incur some cost to
    reduce inequality among others
  • Willingness to pay for equality is sensitive to
    cost theres much less demand for equalization
    at very high prices
  • Uncertainty and risk-aversion is a major driver
    of demand for equality
  • Demand for equality is significantly affected by
    the source of the inequalityearned vs. arbitrary.

64
  • There are substantial gender effects consistent
    with the political gender gap in the U.S.
  • The external validity of the experiment is
    supported by correlations with reported political
    preferences, and by performance of the
    non-student sample

65
To be done
  • More integrated analysis of relative weights on
    self-interest, risk-aversion, and social
    preferences (values, fairness preferences) in
    determining tax choices.
  • Calculation of implied voting outcomes and
    comparison with observed degrees of
    redistribution in U.S. and other countries.
  • Using an explicit Social Welfare Function to
    calculate aggregate utility maximizing tax
    choices.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com