Lecture IIIB2: Financial Leverage and Capital Structure Policy Ch. 16 PowerPoint PPT Presentation

presentation player overlay
1 / 37
About This Presentation
Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Lecture IIIB2: Financial Leverage and Capital Structure Policy Ch. 16


1
Lecture IIIB-2 Financial Leverage and Capital
Structure Policy (Ch. 16)
  • Overview
  • 1. Does leverage affect firm value in a perfect
    capital market?
  • 1.1 An example
  • 1.2 Home-made leverage
  • 1.3 MM proposition I
  • 1.4 Effect of leverage on return (MM II) and
    risk
  • (1) MM II
  • (2) Risk-return trade off
  • 2. MM with corporate taxes
  • 3. MM with bankruptcy costs
  • 3.1 Bankruptcy costs
  • 3.2 MM with bankruptcy costs

2
Overview
  • For the discussion of cost of capital, we take
    the capital structure of a firm as given. Now we
    look at the effect of capital structure on the
    firms value.
  • Capital structure policy refers to a decision on
    the mix of debt and equity for a given asset
    size. Our goal is to find out an optimal capital
    structure of a firm.
  • Major results are Modigliani and Miller (MM)
    propositions I and II.

3
1. Does leverage affect firm value in a perfect
capital market?
  • 1.1 An Example
  • The ABC (Amazing Brew Coffee) Company is
    reviewing its capital structure.
  • Assume no taxes and a perfect capital market.
  • The company has no debt.
  • All operating income is paid out as dividends.
  • Its current position is as follows

4
1.1 An example.. Table 1 current structure
  • Mr. Modigliani, the firm's president, proposes
    to issue 1,000 of debt at 10 and use the
    proceeds to repurchase 50 shares. His analysis
    follows.

5
1.1 An example.. Table 2 Proposed structure
6
1.1 An example..Figure 1 Financial leverage,
EPS and EBIT
7
1.1 An example.. some conclusions from Figure 1
  • Let us draw some conclusions from Figure 1.
  • The effect of financial leverage depends on ABCs
    EBIT. At a high level of EBIT, leverage is
    beneficial.
  • Under the expected scenario (i.e., state 2),
    leverage increases ROE and EPS.
  • Shareholders, however, are exposed to more risk
    under the proposed capital structure since the
    ROE and EPS are more variable and sensitive to
    changes in EBIT.

8
1.1 An example.. Mr. Modiglianis argument
  • Mr. Jack Modiglianis argument
  • Since we expect operating income to be 250
    which is above the critical level of 200, the
    shareholders will be better off with levered
    capital structure.
  • Indifference EBIT Note from Figure 1 that EPS
    (earnings per share) is 2 under current and
    proposed capital structure when EBIT equals to
    200. How do we find out the indifference
    EBIT?
  • Let X denote EBIT. Under current structure,
    EPS is simply X/100. Under the proposed
    structure, you pay interest of 100, and there
    are a total of 50 shares, so EPS is (X?100)/50.
    Equate these two EPSs and solve for X gives
    X200.

9
1.2 Home-made leverage
  • Ms. Jane Millers counter-argument
  • Leverage will help the shareholders as long as
    operating income is above 200. But you ignore
    the possibility of investors borrowing on their
    own account.
  • Suppose that a person borrows 20 and puts up
    20 of her own money. She then invests a total
    of 40 in two unlevered ABC shares.
  • To see Ms. Jane Millers view, lets consider two
    cases
  • Case 1 Proposed capital structure. Buy 1
    levered share at 20
  • Case 2 No change in capital structure. Borrow
    20 use 20 of her own to buy 2 un-levered
    shares

10
(No Transcript)
11
1.2 Home-made leverage
  • Payoff from case 1 and case 2 are identical.
  • Payoffs of 1 levered share is equal to the payoff
    of the home-made portfolio of stock and
    borrowing.
  • Value of 1 levered share Value of the portfolio
  • The portfolio has 2 un-levered shares purchased
    with 20 borrowing and 20 of your own money.
  • Value of 1 levered share (202 - 20
    borrowing) 20
  • ? Levered share price 20.

12
1.3 MM proposition I
  • With perfect capital markets and no taxes, a
    change in capital structure does not add any
    value to the shareholders.
  • Formally, this is MM proposition I
  • VU VL EL DL ,
  • where,VU ? value of the unlevered firm
  • VL ? value of the levered firm
  • DL ? market value of equity
  • EL ? market value of debt.

13
1.3 MM proposition I.. Unlevering the stock
  • One more thing before we leave MM I.
  • Example Unlevering the stock
  • Suppose ABC adopts the proposed capital
    structure.
  • Suppose that our investor prefers the original
    (unlevered) capital structure. How can this
    investor unlever the stock to re-create the
    original payoffs?
  • Suppose she buys one levered share at 20 and
    lends 20 at 10.
  • She receives earnings for 1 share and interest
    from her 20 lending.
  • Her total payoffs are exactly same as the
    original payoffs of two unlevered shares. (See
    Table 5).

14
1.3 MM proposition I.. Unlevering the stock..
unlever the stock by buying one share and
lending 20
15
1.4 Effect of leverage on return (MM II) and risk
  • (1) Leverage and equity returns MM II
  • For our discussion of the cost of capital, we
    have taken the firms capital structure as given.
  • We now look at how the cost of capital changes
    with a change in capital structure.
  • Our goal to find out an optimal or target
    capital structure, which maximizes the firm value
    or equivalently minimizes the cost of capital.
  • We take the cost of debt as constant, at least,
    initially.
  • In order to find out the WACC, we need to find
    out the relation between return on equity and
    capital structure.

16
1.4 (1) MM II
  • Consider ABCs expected returns in two cases
    (Table 6).
  • Intuitively, what is happening here?

In all-equity case, Jane earns 12.5 on her
2,000 equity. In levered case, she earns 12.5
on 1,000 equity, and additional 2.5 (i.e.,
12.5 - 10). Her total return on 1,000 equity
is 15 1,00012.5 1,000(12.5 -
10) 1,000 12.5 (1,000/1,000)(12.5
- 10)
17
1.4 (1) MM II..
  • Suppose Jane puts only 500 equity and borrows
    1,500 at 10.
  • From her 500 equity, she earns 12.5 return.
  • From her 1,500 borrowings, she earns 2.5
    (i.e., 12.5 - 10).
  • Total payoff on her 500 equity is
  • 50012.5 1,500(12.5 - 10)
  • 500 12.5 (1,500/500) (12.5 - 10)
  • Total rate of return on her 500 equity is
  • 12.5 (1,500/500) (12.5 - 10) or more
    generally
  • RE RA (D/E)(RA - RD ), where RA return
    on asset.

18
1.4 (1) MM II..
  • Leverage and equity returns (another derivation
    formal)
  • RA Expected operating income / Market value of
    a firm
  • MM I says that capital structure does not affect
    a firms value. So, RA is independent of its
    debt decision.
  • A firm is a portfolio of debt (D) and equity (E).
    So, RA is an weighted average of returns on
    debt and equity.
  •  
  • Rearranging, we have MM II

19
1.4 (1) MM II..
  • cost of capital

RE RA (RA - RD )(D/E)
WACC RA
RD
D/E
20
1.4 (1) MM II.. Another look at indifferece EBIT
What if Jane does not get any extra earnings from
debt? Then, in levered case, her return on equity
is equal to that in all-equity case. It is her
return on equity at indifference EBIT.
21
1.4 (1) MM II.. Another look at indifferece
EBIT..
  • In out ABC example, borrowing rate is 10.
    Total size of asset is 2,000. When RA10, ABC
    makes 2,00010 200, which must be the
    indifference EBIT.

22
1.4 (1) MM II.. Another look at indifferece
EBIT..
  • Indifference EBIT based on ROE ROA (D/E)(ROA
    - RD ).
  • At an indifference EBIT, the EPS of the levered
    and unlevered share is identical.
  • Stock price still remains at 20 in our ABC
    example. At indifference EBIT, EPS/Price is also
    identical for levered and unlevered capital
    structure.
  • Under an unlevered structure, EPS/Price ROE(All
    E) ROA.
  • Under a levered structure, EPS/Price ROE
    (Levered).
  • So at an indifference EBIT, ROE (Levered) ROA,
    which implies ROA RD.
  • This makes sense. When ROA RD, Jane earns
    only enough operating income to cover her
    interest payment, and there is no beneficial
    effect of leverage. Hence ROE (Levered) is same
    as the ROE of all equity case, which is equal to
    the ROA.

23
1.4 (2) Risk-Return trade-off
  • MM I A firm's leverage does not affect its
    value.
  • MM II return on equity increases as leverage
    increases.
  • So, as leverage increases, the rate of return on
    equity goes up, but the value of the firm stays
    constant. How can they be reconciled?
  • What is happening is that risk is increasing as
    leverage increases.

24
1.4 (2) Risk-Return trade-off..
  • A firms beta is a weighted average of the betas
    of debt and equity
  • ?A D/(DE)?D E/(DE)?E.
  • Rearranging,
  • ?E ?A (?A - ?D )(D/E).
  • With 50 debt and 50 equity (D/E 1), ?D 0, we
    have ?E 2?A.
  • Two components of risk in equity beta.
  • Business risk ?A measures the riskiness of the
    firms asset primarily arising from the nature of
    the firms operation.
  • Financial risk ?A (D/E) depends on the firms
    financial policy.

25
2. MM with corporate taxes
  • Interest expenses are tax deductible. Debt
    financing reduces tax bill, and thus has value.
    To see this, let us compare two firms U and L.
    They are identical except for a 200 debt at 10
    for levered firm L.
  • Suppose corporate tax rate is 30. Then
    relative to firm U,
  • Firm Ls taxable income goes down by the interest
    expense.
  • Interest expense DRD 20010 20
  • Firm Ls tax goes down by 20Tc 2030 6.
    The tax saving due to interest expense is called
    the interest tax shield.
  • Suppose this is a perpetual borrowing. Then PV
    of the interest tax shield is 60. This is
    6/0.1 (DRD) Tc / RD DTc.

26
2. MM with corporate taxes..
  • So, the levered firm L is more valuable than
    unlevered firm U by the PV of interest tax
    shield, which equals to DTc for a perpetual
    debt.
  • MM proposition I with corporate taxes VL VU
    PV tax shield. 
  • In the special case of permanent debt VL VU
    Tc D,
  • where VL ? value of levered firm, and VU ? value
    of all-equity firm. 
  • MM's Proposition II with corporate taxes The
    expected return on the common stock of a levered
    firm increases in proportion to the D/E ratio and
    (1?TC ) the rate of increase depends on the
    spread between ? and RD . Formally, (? ? cost
    of capital for unlevered firm),

27
2. MM with corporate taxes..
28
3. MM with bankruptcy costs
  • Given MM results so far, what should firms do?
    They should borrow as much as possible to gain
    the maximum possible tax shield. But in fact
    they do not borrow very much. Some typical debt
    ratios are given in the table below.
  •  
  • In order to explain why firms do not borrow more,
    we now turn to bankruptcy costs.

29
3. MM with bankruptcy costs 3.1 Bankruptcy
costs
  • Costs of financial distress are  
  • Direct costs of bankruptcy.
  • Indirect costs of bankruptcy.
  • Agency costs of financial distress.
  • (1) Direct Bankruptcy Costs
  • Legal and administrative costs in bankruptcy and
    liquidation.
  • Warner (1977, Journal of Finance, pp. 337-347)
    reported that direct bankruptcy costs were on
    average 5.3 of the overall market value of his
    sample firms.
  • These magnitudes are small relative to the tax
    advantage of debt.

30
3.1 Bankruptcy costs..
  • (2) Indirect Costs of Bankruptcy
  • Costs involved with the difficulties of running a
    business while it is going through bankruptcy.
  • These costs are probably fairly substantial,
    perhaps of the same order of magnitude as a
    strike.
  • However, they are still small relative to the tax
    shield on debt.
  • (3) Agency Costs of Financial Distress
  • Costs associated with distortion of firms
    incentives.
  • Suppose a firm has 1,000 in cash the day before
    its 5,000 debt comes due. If the equity-holders
    (or the managers acting on their behalf) do
    nothing then the firm will go bankrupt and they
    will get nothing. What should they do? The
    manager might go to a Casino.

31
3.1 Bankruptcy costs..
  • In another case, the firm might forego good
    projects, where equity-holders have to share
    rewards with bondholders.
  • Suppose the firm has no cash and has 10,000
    debt. If it does nothing, the firm will go
    bankrupt. Suppose the firm has the following
    investment opportunity 
  • Invest 2,000 Returns 11,000 with
    certainty
  • This is clearly a very attractive project. Is it
    worth the firm doing it?
  • If they do it, bondholders get 10,000.
    Equity-holders will not put up the money for
    investment since, even though it's a very good
    project
  • Return to equity-holders' - 2,000 1,000 -
    1,000.

32
3.2 MM with bankruptcy costs
  • If firms have a high D/E ratio, they have a high
    probability of bankruptcy. Incorporate
    bankruptcy cost into MM
  • There is a trade-off between the tax advantage of
    leverage and the disadvantage of leverage caused
    by the costs of financial distress.

33
3.2 MM with bankruptcy costs..(Figure 4) D/E and
firm value
34
3.2 MM with bankruptcy costs..(Figure 5) D/E and
cost of capital
35
3.2 MM with bankruptcy costs..(Figure 6)
36
3.2 MM with bankruptcy costs..
  • How can this theory be applied in practice?
  • One can use standard NPV techniques to estimate
    the value of an all-equity financed firm.
  • One can discount each year's interest tax shields
    to estimate the PV of the interest tax shields.
  • This leaves the costs of financial distress.
    Direct measurement of the costs of financial
    distress is not usually possible.

37
3.2 MM with bankruptcy costs..
  • How can one find the optimal capital structure?
  • Over time a firm's managers are able to get some
    idea of their firm's costs of financial distress
    and choose the debt ratio taking this into
    account.
  • If one capital structure is better than another
    in one industry, the firms using it will tend to
    do better.
  • Over time firms will move toward an optimal
    capital structure.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)