The economics of nonhorizontal merger guidelines - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 23
About This Presentation
Title:

The economics of nonhorizontal merger guidelines

Description:

Professor, Athens University of Economics and Business, Greece and. Member, European Advisory Group in ... Xavier Vives (IESE Business School, Barcelona) ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:77
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 24
Provided by: rose68
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: The economics of nonhorizontal merger guidelines


1
The economics of non-horizontal merger guidelines
  • Nikos Vettas
  • Professor, Athens University of Economics and
    Business, Greece and
  • Member, European Advisory Group in Competition
    Policy (Chief Economist Group, DG-Competition)
  • Research Fellow, Centre for Economic Policy
    Research, London
  • Athens, June 2 2007

2
The issue non-horizontal merger guidelines
  • Non-horizontal mergers
  • - vertical
  • - conglomerate
  • EU guidelines?
  • Compare to Horizontal merger guidelines
  • Compare to US non-horizontal guidelines

3
European Commission public consultation
  • Draft merger guidelines circulated February 2007
  • Public consultation
  • - started February 13, 2007
  • - ended May 12, 2007
  • Commissioner Neelie Kroes providing clear and
    predictable guidance for businesses
  • DG - Enterprise and Industry The
    Efficiency-Enhancing Effects of Non-Horizontal
    Mergers (RBB Economics report)

4
EAGCP preliminary paper (advisory note)
  • ? EAGCP (Economic Advisory Group in Competition
    Policy)
  • ? Mergers subgroup
  • Marc Ivaldi (University of Toulouse)
  • Bruce Lyons (University of East Anglia)
  • Monika Schnitzer (University of Munich)
  • John Van Reenen (London School of Economics)
  • Frank Verboven (University of Leuven)
  • Nikos Vettas (Athens University of Economics and
    Business)
  • Xavier Vives (IESE Business School, Barcelona)
  • ? First set of (ten) general principles Spring
    2006
  • First, on key economic differences between
    horizontal mergers and NHM.
  • Second, on what the guidelines should achieve.
  • ? Personal views

5
1. The competitive impact of NHM is fundamentally
different from that of HM.
  • The presumption in a horizontal merger is that it
    directly leads to increased market power and an
    ability to raise prices
  • If the merging parties have market power, a
    horizontal merger will typically remove the
    competitive pricing restraints parties place on
    each other.
  • This is not the case for a non-horizontal merger.
  • Horizontal mergers are among substitutes,
    non-horizontal mergers are among complements.
  • Enhancing efficiency is expected.
  • Principle backed both by economic theory and some
    empirical evidence.
  • The competitive effects of non-horizontal mergers
    will depend on characteristics of the situation
    examined.
  • Important NHM parties often have previous
    contractual relationships, in which case the
    competitive change following a merger will be
    muted. Parties to a horizontal merger typically
    do not have prior contracts.

6
2. NHM have indirect impact on competition.
  • A horizontal merger can harm competition by its
    direct impact on the incentive to raise price.
  • A non-horizontal merger has no direct impact on
    pricing.
  • It may still cause competitive harm through a
    change in supply or procurement policy, or the
    way in which a product range is offered to
    consumers. Then, cost or demand of rivals is
    affected and their pricing changes.
  • The merged firm sometimes has the incentive to
    soften price competition in the downstream market
    in order to protect its upstream profits. This
    situation may be difficult to track, since the
    downstream firm has no incentives to complain.
  • The effect of non-horizontal mergers on
    competitive conditions tends to be limited, since
    NHM parties often have previous contractual
    relationship, e.g. that limits buyer or supplier
    switching, whereas HM parties usually do not have
    prior contract.
  • Indirect effects of non-horizontal mergers can
    potentially impede effective competition, but
    they require a particularly careful analysis in
    order to justify a likelihood of harm.

7
3. Non-horizontal mergers take many forms and
produce a variety of effects.
  • There are canonical models for horizontal
    merger (Bertrand with differentiated products or
    Cournot with homogenous products and capacity
    constraints). Much more difficult to analyze
    non-horizontal mergers, there are many possible
    effects.
  • The Chicago School (no harm) models for NHM
    specify conditions under which there is no loss
    of competition due to a non-horizontal merger.
  • Monopoly profits can be taken only once along a
    vertically linked chain
  • Vertical integration can reduce distortions by
    eliminating double marginalization.
  • Vertical integration often results to production
    and organization efficiencies.
  • Note the same reasoning applies to mergers
    between complements.
  • The Chicago approach relies on particular
    assumptions. In practice, the appropriate theory
    of competitive harm must be carefully tuned to
    the merger in question.

8
4. Market power in an existing market is a
pre-requisite for competitive harm from
foreclosure.
  • This well-established fact provides an essential
    filter for screening out spurious concerts.
  • Market power is a necessary, but not sufficient
    condition for foreclosure.
  • When there is market power at both stages of the
    vertical chain, vertical integration helps to
    avoid double marginalization (that often exists
    in absence of sophisticated contracts) and thus
    results to efficiency gains.
  • Even in the presence of market power, merging
    firms need not have the incentive to take actions
    that would reduce the market available to rivals
    and even if this is a likely consequence, it need
    not result in consumer harm.

9
The main vertical externality double
marginalization

10
Remarks
  • Double marginalization with linear pricing, we
    obtain final prices that are too high for the
    final consumers and also for the sellers.
  • Worse than VI monopoly.
  • Distortion increasing with the number of stages
  • This problem can be resolved with
  • - vertical integration
  • - nonlinear pricing a two-part tariff
  • Who sets the prices? Bargaining?
  • Only problem if market power at both stages.

11
Adding horizontal strategic competition

12
Multiple downstream

13
Common Agency / bottlenecks

14
Other structures

15
5. Stronger efficiency arguments for
non-horizontal mergers than for horizontal
mergers.
  • Modern theory of firm and empirical evidence
    inform us that firm as an institution exists due
    to incomplete contracts and transaction costs,
    which make it more efficient to carry out certain
    activities coordinated within a firm as opposed
    to through markets.
  • If complete contracts could be written (at low
    cost), the need to organize economic activities
    within firms would be limited. However, contracts
    that specify a precise outcome for each possible
    future contingency are too expensive.
  • The efficient range of activities carried out
    within a firm may change over time. A
    non-horizontal merger may be efficiency-enhancing.
  • The downside of a decision error that prohibits a
    merger is likely to be much greater for NHM than
    for horizontal mergers.

16
Example specific investments
  • Assurance of quantity, quality and time of supply
  • Specific production
  • Specific assets danger of opportunistic behavior
    (hold-up) implies below optimal investment
    incentives (Coase, vertical boundaries of the
    firm Williamson Grossman-Hart)
  • Solution? VI? Long-term contracts? Short-term
    contracts?
  • Single sourcing (exclusivity) vs. multiple
    sources.

17
6. NHM Guidelines could enhance the accuracy and
predictability of decisions.
  • Major difficulties inherent in writing detailed
    guidelines.
  • Difficulties based on the very nature of
    non-horizontal mergers and the multiplicity of
    forms they may take.
  • Difficulties are reflected on the current state
    of the academic literature.
  • Having a suitable set of principles to deal with
    NHM is important.
  • They will contribute towards predictability of
    decisions and consistency.
  • Predictability is important, especially to
    businesses and their advisors.
  • Case handlers need guidance.
  • Good guidance will be useful for authorities
    beyond DG-Competition.

18
7. Guidelines should focus on competitive effects
resulting in benefit or harm to consumers (and
not to competitors).
  • Efficiencies that lead to reduction in prices or
    to more attractive product offering may lead to
    reduction of competitors market share, but are
    to be welcomed as consumer benefit.
  • Elimination of double-marginalization can create
    an incentive to reduce customer prices.
  • Not always a double margin to be eliminated, even
    in the presence of imperfect competition, because
    parties have an incentive to contract around this
    source of inefficiency.
  • Pre-merger contracts are very relevant and
    important in this context.
  • Depending on the particular type of market
    structure under investigation studies, double
    marginalization does not necessarily reduce the
    profits of the firms involved.

19
7. (and not to competitors).
  • Particularly important to recognise the benefits
    of anticipated customer price reductions because
    competitors anticipating lost market share have a
    strong incentive to complain loudly to the
    Commission.
  • An expectation of consumer harm needs very
    careful support.

20
8. Guidelines should indicate the methodology of
analysis and the relevant evidence.
  • For actions harmful to consumers, both the
    ability and the incentive of merged firms to take
    such actions should be established.
  • Each particular scenario of harm should rely on a
    package of pre-requisites, e.g. market share,
    product differentiation, feasibility of bundling,
    margins.
  • Other useful information to be considered
    existing contracts, sales practices, procurement
    methods, natural experiments.
  • The assessment of the effects of a vertical
    merger must not presume consumer harm and then
    look for countervailing efficiencies. In other
    words, the model used to analyze a vertical
    merger must allow for potential efficiencies from
    the start and not for competitive harm only.

21
9. Guidelines should distinguish more likely
from less likely competitive harm whenever
possible.
  • Qualitative guidance may be provided on the
    relative risks of different types of harm (e.g.
    there is usually far greater concern if
    foreclosure results in exit, as opposed to
    changes in market share).
  • Safe harbours might be indicated, at least in
    relation to the pre-requisite of market power.
  • If none of the firms involved in a merger has
    significant market power in any of the markets,
    then there is almost always no need for a
    competition authority to scrutinize this
    particular merger.
  • If after a vertical merger the upstream market is
    supplied by vertically integrated firms only,
    there is a risk that upstream firms could sustain
    higher prices for the upstream products, forcing
    (not vertically integrated) downstream firms to
    raise their final prices. Hence the number of
    firms acting in the different markets plays a
    crucial role.
  • Overall, the scale of likelihood should tie
    appropriately with the required standard of proof
    for the Commission.

22
10. Non-horizontal Guidelines should be
consistent with other Guidelines / Notices /
Green Papers.
  • The horizontal merger guidelines can be
    interpreted to define existing market power in
    the context of a non-horizontal merger case (even
    though those guidelines deal directly with
    changes to market power, not the existence of
    market power).
  • There might be some important links to Article
    82, as firms may find ways to establish vertical
    relationships among themselves (e.g. long-term
    specific contracts) that possibly replicate part
    of what would be achieved via a merger.
  • There should also be consistency with notices on
    vertical restraints.

23
Concluding remarks
  • On the role of guidelines.
  • On the role of competition policy (in the general
    mix of economic policy).
  • Competition, free market!
  • Rules to be clear and application of policy
    should be transparent, consistent, efficient and
    predictable.
  • Regulatory cost as an entry cost.
  • Entry! Innovation!
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com