Geographic Integration, Transmission Constraints, and Electricity Restructuring - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 46
About This Presentation
Title:

Geographic Integration, Transmission Constraints, and Electricity Restructuring

Description:

Pennsylvania State University and The Brattle Group, respectively. ... Other papers using a similar model include: Sexton et al. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:130
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 47
Provided by: andrew489
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Geographic Integration, Transmission Constraints, and Electricity Restructuring


1
Geographic Integration, Transmission
Constraints, and Electricity Restructuring
March, 2005 Not for Quotation without Authors
Permission
Andrew N. KleitJames D. Reitzes
  • Pennsylvania State University and The Brattle
    Group, respectively.
  • The authors can be contacted at ank1_at_psu.edu and
    james.reitzes_at_brattle.com.

2
Topics for Discussion
  • How to Estimate Arbitrage Costs
  • How to Modify the Arbitrage Cost Model for
    Electricity Markets in Order to
  • Estimate the Impact of ISO formation on
    Electricity Trading Costs
  • Assess the Prevalence of Binding Transmission
    Constraints under Different Transmission
    Organizational Regimes
  • ? How to Estimate the Shadow Value of Adding
    Further Transmission Capacity
  • All with easily available data!

3
Arbitrage Cost Estimation
  • Basic Methodology

4
Arbitrage Cost Estimation Basic Methodology
  • The basic arbitrage cost model was developed by
    Spiller and Wood (1988), who examined integration
    of regional gasoline markets.
  • Other papers using a similar model include
    Sexton et al. (1991) for celery Kleit and
    Palsson (1996, 1999) for Canadian cement and
    Kleit (1998) in natural gas.

5
Arbitrage Cost Estimation Basic Methodology
(cont.)
  • Use maximum likelihood techniques to distinguish
    two regimes
  • (a) Arbitrage (Unconstrained Trade) -
    inter-regional price differences represent
    marginal trading costs.
  • (b) Autarky - inter-regional price differences
    most likely reflect differing regional supply and
    demand conditions.
  • Under autarky,
  • (i) no trade occurs, or
  • (ii) trade occurs on a long-term contract basis
    but does not respond to short-term
    arbitrage opportunities.

6
Arbitrage Cost Methodology
  • Assume a (stochastic) cost of arbitrage the
    cost of shippinga good from Region 1 to Region 2
    (or vice versa).
  • The price difference between the two regions
    cannot exceed arbitrage costs.

7
Basic Arbitrage Cost Model
  • Let P1 price of the good in Region 1,
  • Let P2 price of the good in Region 2,
  • Let Y P1-P2.
  • Without the threat of arbitrage, the price
    difference between the two regions is determined
    by the autarky relationship
  •   ?PN ? ?, (1)
  • ? constant ? N(0, ?2).

8
Basic Arbitrage Cost Model (cont.)
  • If price in Region 1 becomes much higher than
    price in Region 2, buyers in 1 will arbitrage the
    difference by buying the good in 2 and shipping
    to 1.
  • Now define the arbitrage (i.e., trading) cost of
    sending the good from Region 2 to Region 1
  • T1 T 1 ? 1, (2)
  • ? 1 N(0, ? 12), truncated from below at
    -T1  
  • The reason for the truncation from below is that
    arbitrage costs must be nonnegative, (i.e., T1
    gt0).

9
Basic Arbitrage Cost Model (cont.)
  • Now, an observed price difference, Y P1-P2gt0,
    could result from two possible states
  • (1) autarky (i.e., the absence of arbitrage),
    implying that
  • arbitrage costs exceed the observed price
    difference
  • ?PN Y and T1gtY.
  • (2) arbitrage, implying that the price
    difference would be larger under autarky
  • T1Y and ?PN gt Y.

10
Basic Arbitrage Cost Model (cont.)
  • The likelihood of observing a particular value of
    Y is therefore as follows
  • L(Yi) Likelihood (?PNYi and T1gtYi)
  • Likelihood (T1Yi and ?PNgtYi), (3)
  • L(Yi) f(?PNYi)(1-F(T1Yi))
  • f(T1Yi)(1-F (?PNYi)), (4)
  • where f pdf, Fcdf.
  • This is a variant of Tobit with stochastic limits.

11
An Extension to the Basic Arbitrage Cost Model

  • Autarky price differences should be related to
    structural factors (i.e., cost and demand
    conditions) in each regional market.

(7)
12
Electricity Restructuring and Market Integration
13
Electricity Restructuring and Market Integration
  • ISOs were designed to facilitate wholesale
    electricity trading by lowering trading costs and
    mitigating incentives to manipulate the
    transmission system.
  • --- Has this occurred?
  • Hardly any analysis has been performed on this
    question.
  • Thus, we examine the impact of forming the PJM
    ISO on electricity trading costs between PJM and
    New York and between PJM and the ECAR Reliability
    Region.

14
Modified Arbitrage Cost Model
  • Adding Quantity-Constrained Trade

15
Adjusting the Arbitrage Cost Estimator for
Electricity Markets
  • Since transmission capacity limits and
    institutional impediments may constrain the
    quantity of electricity that can be traded
    between regions, we modify the traditional
    arbitrage cost model to consider three possible
    equilibrium states
  • (1) autarky
  • (2) arbitrage (i.e., unconstrained trade), and
  • (3) quantity-constrained trade.

16
Quantity-Constrained Trade
  • Quantity-constrained trade represents a state
    where trade takes place up to some capacity
    limit, and no more.
  • Capacity limit can be a physical or institutional
    trading barrier.
  • .

17
Quantity-Constrained Trade
  • We express the price differential between regions
    1 and 2 under quantity-constrained trade as
  • Ci Ai - FLOWi ?
  • Zi'? - FLOWi ? (9)
  • Thus, the quantity constrained price difference
    equals the autarky price difference, less FLOW1,
    where FLOW1 represents the change in the price
    difference induced by the flow of electricity
    from one region to another up to the available
    quantity limit.

18
Likelihood Function with Quantity-Constrained
Trade
L(Yi) Likelihood (?PiNYi and T1i Yi)
Likelihood (T1iYi and ?PiN gtYi C1i)
Likelihood (C1iYi and ?PiN gt Yi gtT1i).
(10)
19
Modified Trading Cost Equation
  • We add indicator variables to estimate the impact
    on trading costs of
  • (a) the formation of the PJM ISO (April 1,
    1998)
  • (b) PJMs switch from cost-based to
    market-based
  • bidding (April 1, 1999)
  • Revised trading cost specification is
  • T1 T 1 ß98I98 ß99I99 ? 1,
    (2')
  • where I98 1 after April 1, 1998 else 0
  • I99 1 after April 1, 1999 else 0
  • ? 1 N(0, ? 12), truncated from below at -(T1
    ß98I98 ß98I99)

20
Calculating Regime Probabilities Using
Bayesian Updating
  • From (10), we obtain

Recall Pr(AB) Pr (AnB)/Pr(B). Writing
in likelihood space, Pr(AutarkyYi)
L(AutarkynYi)/L(Yi) We calculate probabilities
similarly for the unconstrained and constrained
trading states.

21
Institutional Detail and Data
22
Institutional Detail
  • Our analysis focuses on arbitrage costs
    involving
  • PJM - New York
  • PJM ECAR
  • On April 1, 1998, the PJM exchange market began
    with only cost-based bidding permitted.
  • However, no explicit mechanism existed for
    monitoring compliance with costs.
  • PJM members were allowed to supply electricity at
    market-based rates outside of PJMs service
    territory (and through bilateral transactions
    within PJMs territory).

23
Institutional Detail (cont.)
  • After April 1, 1999, market-based bids were
    allowed within PJMs service territory.
  • We use indicator variables to distinguish 3
    periods
  • (i) before April 1998
  • (ii) between April 1998 and March 1999
  • (iii) April 1999 and after.

24
Data
  • Time period
  • January 1997-July 2002
  • --- 1350 observations
  • Dependent variable
  • daily electricity prices (PJM, NY, ECAR)
  • --- volume-weighted averages of the contract
    prices
  • for pre-scheduled, day-ahead 1x16
    electricity blocks
  • (Power Markets Week)

25
Data (cont.)
  • Demand shifter
  • temperatures (PJM, NY, ECAR)
  • --- summer and winter degree days calculated
    from NOAA temperature data
  • Cost shifter
  • fuel costs
  • --- Henry Hub gas prices

26
The Results
  • PJM New York

27
Autarky Parameters PJM/NYISO(t-stats in
parentheses)
28
Transaction Costs PJM/NYISO(t-stats in
parenthesis)
29
Mean Transaction Costs PJM/NYISO(/MWh)
30
Expected State Probabilities PJM/NYISO
31
Conclusions PJM-NYISO
  • Transaction costs fell to PJM from NY, subsequent
    to formation of PJM ISO.
  • Transaction costs to NY from PJM rose by more
    than 2/MWh after PJM switched from cost-based to
    market-based bidding.
  • Explanation (1) more inward focus by PJM
    suppliers after market-based bidding (2)
    differing ISO protocols, perhaps.
  • Prevalence of quantity-constrained trade similar
    in each direction for PJM-NY, but results will be
    different for PJM-ECAR!

32
The Results
  • PJM ECAR

33
Autarky Parameters PJM/ECAR(t-stats in
parentheses)
34
Transaction Costs PJM/ECAR(t-stats in
parenthesis)
35
Mean Transaction Costs PJM/ECAR(/MWh)
36
Expected State Probabilities PJM/ECAR
37
Conclusions PJM-ECAR
  • Transaction costs to PJM from ECAR fell by nearly
    1/MWh after formation of PJM exchange market.
  • Improved price discovery, perhaps.
  • Transaction costs to PJM from ECAR rose by more
    than 2/MWh after PJM switched from cost-based to
    market-based bidding.

38
Conclusions PJM-ECAR (cont.)
  • High prevalence of quantity-constrained trade
    when ECAR has higher prices than PJM is striking,
    given apparent lack of binding physical
    transmission constraints moving from PJM into
    ECAR.
  • Results suggest that significant efficiencies in
    transmission usage may arise from PJMs westward
    expansion and the formation of an effective MISO.

39
The Value of Expanding Transmission Capability
40
Estimating the Shadow Cost of Quantitative Trade
Constraints
  • Little research has attempted how to estimate the
    efficiency losses imposed by existing quantity
    constraints on electricity flows.
  • Estimating the shadow cost of quantity
    constraints in terms of their marginal
    contribution to inter-regional price differences
    represents a means of assessing the value that
    additional transfer capability (e.g.,
    transmission capacity) could provide.

41
Estimating the Shadow Cost of Quantitative Trade
Constraints
  • A two-stage process is used to estimate the
    shadow cost arising from quantity constraints
    on electricity flows.
  • (1) We take the observed price difference on each
    day and subtract our estimated mean transaction
    cost, assuming constrained trading.
  • Assuming quantity-constrained trade, an
    incremental increase in electricity flows from a
    lower-priced to a higher-priced region will
    reduce energy costs by the observed price
    difference, less the transaction cost.
  • (2) The amount in (1) is multiplied by the
    estimated probability that the observed
    inter-regional price difference on that day
    is associated with quantity-constrained trade.

42
(No Transcript)
43
(No Transcript)
44
(No Transcript)
45
Estimated Annual Shadow Cost of Quantity Trade
Constraints (/MW)
  • Annual Shadow Cost (Total Shadow Cost)/5.33
    years.
  • Total Shadow Cost S (Actual Daily Observed
    Price Difference - Estimated Mean Transaction
    Cost) (Probability That Observed State Is
    Quantity-Constrained Trade).

46
Conclusions Value ofIncreased Transmission
Capability
  • Additional transmission capability has
    substantial peak load value.
  • Most of shadow value is derived from lessening
    price spikes in summer months.
  • Highest shadow value of increased transmission
    capability is to ECAR from PJM (nearly 19,000
    per MW year), which may not be a physical
    transmission constraint but rather an
    institutional constraint.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com