Learning from Difference: The New Architecture of Experimentalist Governance in the EU - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 24
About This Presentation
Title:

Learning from Difference: The New Architecture of Experimentalist Governance in the EU

Description:

Title: Learning from Difference: The New Architecture of Experimentalist Governance in the EU Author: Jonathan Zeitlin Last modified by: Jonathan Zeitlin – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:70
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 25
Provided by: Jonatha443
Learn more at: https://europe.wisc.edu
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Learning from Difference: The New Architecture of Experimentalist Governance in the EU


1
Learning from Difference The New Architecture
of Experimentalist Governance in the EU
  • Charles Sabel (Columbia Law School)Jonathan
    Zeitlin (University of Wisconsin-Madison)

2
A novel polity without a state
  • Despite recurrent crises, the EU is creating a
    single market, while constructing a framework
    within which MS can protect public health and
    safety (broadly understood) in nationally diverse
    ways

3
A new governance architecture
  • EUs regulatory successes rest on a new
    architecture of decision making
  • A recursive process of framework rule making and
    revision based on networked deliberation among
    European and national actors
  • New architecture increasingly widespread across
    EU policy making despite not being explicitly
    grounded in Treaties and directives

4
I. Elements of the new architecture
  • Framework goals and metrics for assessing
    progress towards them established jointly by EU
    institutions and MS
  • E.g. full employment, good water status,
    unified energy grid
  • Lower-level units (national ministries,
    regulatory authorities, collaborating actors)
    given freedom to advance these goals as they see
    fit

5
Elements of the new architecture (2)
  • In return for autonomy, lower-level units must
  • report regularly on their performance, esp. as
    measured by agreed metrics
  • participate in peer reviews where their results
    are compared to others pursuing other means to
    same ends
  • Framework goals, metrics, procedures
    periodically revised in light of experience
  • By actors who initially established them other
    participants whose views are recognized as
    important for full fair deliberation (e.g.
    civil society orgs.)

6
Experimentalist governance as a functional concept
  • 4 key architectural elements as a set of
    necessary functions which can be performed
    through a variety of institutional arrangements
  • No one-to-one mapping of governance functions to
    specific institutional mechanisms, and vice versa
  • A single governance function (e.g.
    monitoring/review of implementation) can be
    performed by multiple institutional devices,
    singly or in combination
  • A single institutional mechanism (e.g. formal
    peer review) can perform several analytically
    distinct governance functions

7
EU governance as directly-deliberative polyarchy
(DDP)
  • Deliberative uses argument to disentrench
    settled practices and redefine interests/preferenc
    es
  • Directly-deliberative uses the concrete
    experience of actors differing reactions to
    current problems to generate novel possibilities
    for consideration
  • Polyarchic a system in which local units learn
    from, discipline, and set goals for each other

8
A machine for learning from diversity
  • Well-suited to heterogeneous settings like the EU
  • where local units face similar problems, and can
    learn from each others separate efforts to solve
    them, even if solutions can rarely be generalized
    straightforwardly
  • Transforms diversity into an asset rather than a
    obstacle to closer integration
  • A system of experimentalist governance
  • in the pragmatist sense of systematically
    provoking doubt about its own assumptions and
    practices, while treating all solutions as
    provisional and corrigible

9
Multiple routes to the EUs new governance
architecture
  • Federated regulation in privatized infrastructure
  • Fora councils of regulators in telecoms, energy
  • Networked administrative agencies protecting
    public health and safety
  • Drug authorization, occupational health safety,
    (environmental protection)
  • Open Methods of Coordination (OMC)
  • Employment, social protection/inclusion,
    education/training
  • Operational coordination among natl authorities
    EU agencies in Justice Home Affairs

10
Extensions of the new architecture
  • Responses to catastrophe
  • Food safety, maritime safety
  • Prudential regulation in advance of failure
  • Financial services (Lamfalussy Process)
  • Revision of existing centralized regulation
  • Competition/antitrust policy, state aid
  • From rules to rights
  • Anti-discrimination policy, fundamental rights

11
Minimal scope conditions
  • Scope conditions for experimentalist governance
    broader than historical contexts of emergence in
    EU
  • Strategic uncertainty
  • Policy makers recognize that they do not know how
    to achieve their declared goals
  • Multi-polar or polyarchic distribution of power
  • No single actor able to impose preferred solution
    w/o taking into account views of others
  • Opens up possibility of transforming distributive
    bargaining into deliberative problem solving
    through institutional mechanisms of
    experimentalist governance

12
II. Responses to standard objections
  • Undermining the rule of law?
  • Lack of accountability in recursive rule making
  • Ineffectiveness/lack of teeth?
  • Deliberative governance as soft law
  • At best a secondary complement to hard law
    based on political bargaining
  • Subverting democracy?
  • Technocratic deliberation among transnational
    expert networks as a threat to democracy

13
The limits of principal-agent governance
  • Accountability in representative democracy is
    based on principal-agent model
  • But principal-agent accountability depends on
    ability of principals to specify goals precisely
    enough to give clear instructions to agents or to
    recognize reliably when actions do or dont serve
    specified ends
  • Model breaks down under conditions of
    uncertainty/volatility when solutions to problems
    can only be identified as they are being pursued
  • Recursive redefinition of ends and means in EU
    experimentalist governance as a response to this
    situation

14
dynamic accountability through peer review as
an alternative
  • Dynamic accountability not as conformity to a
    preset rule, but as requirement to explain
    reasons for exercising discretion in choosing one
    particular way of advancing a common project,
    subject to review by peers with sufficient
    knowledge to evaluate such explanations
  • Peer review of EU experimentalist governance
    through fora, networked agencies, councils of
    regulators, OMCs
  • Processes through which EU decision-makers learn
    from and correct each other even as they set
    goals and performance standards for the Union

15
Experimentalist governance is not soft law
  • New architecture routinely results in revisions
    of EU law, or elaboration of revisable standards
    mandated by law and principles that may
    eventually be given binding force
  • For every decision-making process that produces
    non-binding legal sanctions, there is typically
    another in the same domain where non-compliance
    can have draconian consequences

16
Destabilization regimes
  • Sanctions in EU experimentalist governance often
    take the form of what may be called a
    destabilization regime
  • A set of mechanisms for unblocking impasses in
    framework rule making and revision by rendering
    the current situation untenable while suggesting
    -- or causing the parties to suggest --plausible
    and superior alternatives

17
Varieties of destabilization regimes
  • Destabilization regimes can take many forms
  • Requirement to deliberate in public
  • E.g. EU food safety conflict clause
  • In cases of disagreement over scientific risk
    assessment between EFSA and national authorities,
    both sides are obliged to submit a joint document
    explaining their differences
  • But doing so would put both parties at risk
    because either could lose the debate in full
    public view, while political instrumentalization
    of the issue could endanger future collaboration
    and scientific exchange
  • This gives both parties strong incentives to
    continue deliberation until an agreement that
    both can defend is public is reached

18
The right to challenge and the obligation to
explain
  • E.g. EU competition policy network
  • The Commission has the right to take over cases
    from national competition authorities, but must
    formally justify its decision to other members of
    the network
  • Not just a vertical but also a horizontal right
    of challenge any member of the network can
    demand a review of another national competition
    authoritys handling of a case

19
Penalty defaults
  • At the other extreme are penalty defaults
  • Instead of imposing deliberation requirements,
    the central authority creates brutal
    disincentives for refusal to deliberate
  • Rules sufficiently unpalatable to all parties
    that each is motivated to contribute to an
    information-sharing regime that allows fair and
    effective regulation of their interdependence
  • In a world where standard rule making produces
    such unpredictable consequences as to be
    unworkable, the easiest way to generate penalty
    defaults is to (threaten to) engage in
    traditional rule making

20
An EU example the Florence Electricity Forum
  • Unblocking of deliberative impasses on thorny
    issues such as cross-border tarification by
    Commission threats to invoke competition law
    powers (antitrust, merger control, state aid
    rules)
  • Could leave obstructive/intransigent actors worse
    off than a compromise reached in the Forum
  • Commissions powers of legislative initiative and
    delegated regulation as a means of inducing MS
    and private actors to cooperate in framework rule
    making for fear of unpredictable consequences of
    an imposed alternative

21
Bargaining in the shadow of hierarchy or
deliberating when hierarchy becomes a shadow?
  • From this it follows that EU experimentalist
    governance can rarely be understood as regulatory
    cooperation in the shadow of traditional public
    hierarchy
  • Bargaining in the shadow of the state (Scharpf,
    Héritier) assumes that public authorities can
    effectively regulate in case of deadlock,
    mismanagement, or policy failure
  • But both in the case of the public deliberation
    and penalty default mechanisms, the EU induces
    the actors to provide rules for themselves,
    presumably because it cannot itself provide
    defaults that would do the job as well or better
  • Not bargaining in the shadow of hierarchy, but
    deliberating when hierarchy becomes a shadow

22
The Florence Forum revisited
  • Competition law as a negative control
    instrument, based on ex post, case-by case
    procedures, which cant produce fine-tuned
    solutions like those developed by the Forum
  • Further legislation, even if more stringent and
    detailed, still needs to be interpreted and
    implemented at national level cant address all
    future needs in a rapidly evolving policy area
  • Hence continuing need for rule development and
    coordination through networked governance

23
Democratizing destabilization
  • Networked, experimentalist governance/DDP not
    intrinsically democratic
  • But dynamic accountability through peer review
    subject to penalty defaults has a potentially
    democratizing destabilization effect on domestic
    politics and the EU itself
  • Requirement that each national administration
    justify its rule choices publicly, in light of
    comparable choices by others, allows domestic
    actors to contest official proposals on the basis
    of richer information about feasible alternatives
    than would otherwise be available

24
Transparency and participation as procedural
requirements
  • Transparency and participation as foundations for
    democratizing destabilization
  • EU becoming increasingly transparent and
    participatory
  • ECJ case law decisions on administrative
    procedure and access to documents
  • Treaty revisions and EU regulations
  • Progressive elaboration of legal transparency
    requirements in EU networked governance
  • Increasing tendency to establish requirements for
    ensuring active participation by a broad range of
    stakeholders (incl. civil society)
  • Directives establishing networked agencies and
    other EU regulatory frameworks (e.g. water)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com