Course: Executives, Bureaucracies and Courts Instructor: Prof. Fabio Franchino The European Court of Justice, National Governements, and Legal Integration in the European Union Geoffrey Garrett, R. Daniel Keleman, Heiner Schultz

1 / 18
About This Presentation
Title:

Course: Executives, Bureaucracies and Courts Instructor: Prof. Fabio Franchino The European Court of Justice, National Governements, and Legal Integration in the European Union Geoffrey Garrett, R. Daniel Keleman, Heiner Schultz

Description:

Course: Executives, Bureaucracies and Courts Instructor: Prof. Fabio Franchino The European Court of Justice, National Governements, and Legal Integration –

Number of Views:292
Avg rating:3.0/5.0

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Course: Executives, Bureaucracies and Courts Instructor: Prof. Fabio Franchino The European Court of Justice, National Governements, and Legal Integration in the European Union Geoffrey Garrett, R. Daniel Keleman, Heiner Schultz


1
Course Executives, Bureaucracies and Courts
Instructor Prof. Fabio FranchinoThe European
Court of Justice, National Governements, and
Legal Integration in the European UnionGeoffrey
Garrett, R. Daniel Keleman, Heiner Schultz
  • Biassoni Davide
  • matr. n. R07434
  • Graduate School in Social, Economic and Political
    Sciences
  • Ph.D. program in Political Studies

2
Preliminary remarks
  • the accretion of power by the European Court of
    Justice (ECJ) is the clearest manifestation of
    the transfer of sovereignty from nation-states to
    a supranational institution.
  • the ECJ interprets EU treaties as if they
    represent a de facto constitution for Europe and
    exercises judicial review over laws and practises
    within member states. The ECJ has the power to
    declare extant national laws and the behaviour of
    national governments "EU-unconstitutional".
  • Two interpretation of the European legal system's
    evolution
  • legal autonomy approach the ECJ has been able to
    push forward its European integration agenda
    against the interests of some member states.
  • political power approach national governments
    have not been passive and unwilling victims of
    European legal integration ? member governments
    (MGs) supported the ECJ activism and autonomy
    and, in turn, the judges of the ECJ are reticent
    to make decisions of which governments
    disapprove.

3
Research outline
  • Analysis strategic interaction between ECJ and
    national governments.
  • Objectives the specifying conditions under which
    the ECJ makes decision that declare illegal
    national laws, regulations, or practises and
    exploring how MGs react to them.
  • game theoretic model of the interaction between
    ECJ and MGs.
  • Three hypothesis
  • the greater the clarity of ECJ case law
    precedent, the lesser the likelihood that the
    Court will tailor its decisions to the
    anticipated reactions of member governments (H1).
  • the greater the domestic costs of an ECJ ruling
    to a litigant member governments, the lesser the
    likelihood that the government will abide by an
    ECJ decision that adversely affects its interests
    (H2).
  • the greater the activism of the ECJ and the
    larger the number of member governments adversely
    affected by it, the greater the likelihood that
    responses by litigant governments will move from
    individual noncompliance to coordinated
    retaliation (H3).

4
Further remarks
  • Common assumption ECJ is a strategic actor that
    is sensitive to the preferences of EU member
    governments.
  • ECJ status independent and impartial interpreter
    of EU law ? ECJ has to minimize the appearance of
    succumbing to political pressures from interested
    parties.
  • Three lines of cases that have been central to
    the broader process of European integration
  • Bans on agricultural imports, where the ECJ
    decisions stood on the front line in the battle
    between protectionism and liberalisation.
  • Equal treatment of the sexes to occupational
    pensions.
  • ECJ decisions concerning state liability for the
    violation of EU law.

5
The legal politics game
6
The legal politics game
  • noncooperative stage game
  • the game is repeated indefinitely
  • the first move is made by ECJ national
    law/practise is consistent with EU law? if yes
    ? status quo (Cc) conciliation if no ? if the
    member government (MG) abides by the ECJ decision
    then it has to change its national law/practise,
    else the MG has 3 types of reply
  • in the second round, the Court takes into account
    the information it gained in the previous play of
    the game ? actors update their information.
  • preference ordering of the ECJ Ca gt Cd gt Cc gt Cr
  • preference ordering of the MG Gc gt Gr gt Ga gt Gd

7
The legal politics game
  • the ECJ has a clear interest in extending the
    Community law and its own authority to interpret
    it.
  • Assumptions concerning MGs
  • they support a powerful system of EU law in which
    the ECJ faithfully implement the governments'
    intentions as laid out in the EU treaty base.
  • the more a member government benefits from the
    economic exchanges made possible by the rule of
    law in Europe, the greater is likely to be its
    respect for ECJ decisions.
  • adverse decisions will always be costly for MGs ?
    the best outcome is the conciliation (status
    quo).
  • General equilibria
  • if the other MGs support the litigant government,
    the ECJ is not inclined to deliver an adverse
    decision, so that the outcome is the status quo
  • else if they don't support the litigant MG, then
    the ECJ rules against the litigant MG which in
    turn accepts the decision.

8
ECJ precedents
  • a clear tension the desire not to make judgments
    that adversely affect the interests of MGs and
    the importance of legal consistency.
  • cost of inconsistency for EJC are a function of
    the clarity of existing precedent.
  • H1 the greater the clarity of EU treaties, case
    precedent, and legal norms in support of an
    adverse judgment, the greater the likelihood that
    the ECJ will rule against a litigant government.
  • The preference ordering of the ECJ should be
    modified to take into account the clarity of
    legal precedent in a specific case. What if the
    ECJ has to take an adverse decision on the basis
    of a case law precedent?
  • Adverse decision could become a dominant strategy
    (Cr gt Cc), no matter the reaction of the litigant
    government and also the other EU governments ?
    the EJC declare a given law/practise to be
    illegal and the best outcome (Gc) for the member
    government is no longer feasible.
  • Clarity of precedent it is ultimately an
    empirical question.

9
The litigant government
  • Governments will more likely abide by an ECJ
    adverse decision when the interests adversely
    affected by the decision are not damaged in a
    great extent.
  • H2 The greater the domestic costs of an ECJ
    ruling to a litigant government, the lesser the
    likelihood that the government will abide by an
    adverse decision.
  • if the government is sufficiently concerned about
    the domestic costs of an adverse decision, then
    Gd gt Ga ? in this case the litigant government
    has a dominant strategy in not accepting the ECJ
    decision, no matter the other governments would
    do. 

10
Other member governments
  • The most effective way that MGs can restrict ECJ
    activism is to revise EU treaties but the
    threshold to such constitutional revision is very
    high unanimity ratifications. An easier path
    is to passage of new EU legislation (directives,
    regulations, decisions, secondary legislation) to
    counteract the effects of ECJ decisions.
  • When should we expect the EU governments
    collectively seek to restrain ECJ activism?
  • the greater the importance of a particular case
    to more MGs, the greater the likelihood that they
    will collectively support a litigant government
    seeking to defy an adverse judgment.
  • the greater the number of cases within a similar
    branch of the law that the Court adversely
    decides, the greater the likelihood of a
    collective response to constrain the ECJ.
  • H3 the greater the potential costs of a case,
    the larger the number of governments potentially
    affected by it, and the large the number of
    adverse decisions the ECJ makes in similar areas
    of the law, the greater the likelihood that the
    EU member governments will respond collectively
    to restrain EU activism. 
  • The litigant MG would know that its defiance
    would be supported by its EU colleagues and so it
    will never accept an adverse decision because it
    knows it can rely on the support of the other MGs
    to pass new secondary legislation or treaty
    revisions (Gr gt Ga). As for the ECJ Cc gt Cr, it
    will not make an adverse decision.

11
Three lines of cases
  • a) Import bans on agricultural products
  • Domestic deregulation was combined with
    reregulation at the EU level.
  • 1974 the Charmasson case involved a request of
    annulment of a quota for banana imports imposed
    by the French government on Oct. 28th 1969.
  • The contradictions between a free-trade article
    (Article 33) and the agricultural provisions
    (Article 38-46) gave the ECJ leeway in
    interpreting the Rome treaty. The ECJ made a bold
    pro-integration interpretation by ruling that
    national marketing organizations could not stand
    in the way of free trade after the end of the
    transition period ? the French government opposed
    this interpretation and was likely to defy the
    ECJ (consistency with H2). And also the ECJ's
    behaviour is consistent with H3 it had little
    reason to expect a collective response from the
    member governments ? treaty revision was very
    unlikely as few other products had not yet been
    incorporated into the Common Agricultural Policy
    (Cd gt Cc).
  • the Potato case the U.K. Government argued that
    under special provision pertaining to its
    accession to the EU in 1973, it was entitled to
    maintain national market organizations that
    existed at that time (in spite of the Treaty of
    Rome) ? by the precedent of the Charmasson case,
    the ECJ ruled against the U.K (consistency with
    H1).

12
  • the Sheep Meat case the French government did
    not challenge principle encompassed in the
    Charmasson or Potato case, but just asked a
    temporal extension to maintain its national
    market organization for mutton. As the ECJ held
    that the French sheep meat regime had to be
    discontinued, France refused to comply with the
    Court's ruling ? "sheep meat war" the domestic
    costs of the Sheep Meat decision led the French
    government to defy the ECJ (consistency with H2).
  • Could the ECJ make an adverse decision against
    France?
  • if the ECJ violated the precedent, it would lose
    legitimacy as an impartial arbiter.
  • the Court had little reason to believe that the
    other MGs would join the litigant French
    government.
  • Solution a common market organization for sheep
    meat was established at the Dublin meeting of the
    Council in May 1980. French President's proposal
    to reform the ECJ was not supported by other
    member governments.

13
b) Equal treatment of the sexes
  • art. 119 Treaty of Rome equal pay for equal work
    --gt equal conditions for men and women.
  • Controversial case age pensions ? Defrenne No.
    1, 2 Bilka with the latter one, occupational
    pensions constituted pay under Article 119
    occupational pensions constituted pay and that
    denying access to an occupational pension scheme
    to a group consisting predominantly of women
    violated Article 119.
  • this would seem inconsistent with H3 because the
    Court could have expected a collective
    restraining response from the EU member
    governments. The Council, two months after Bilka,
    passed a new directive on occupational pensions.
  • the Barber case the Court ruled that sex-based
    differences in pensionable ages violated Article
    119 and had to be eliminated ? its language was
    very vague and ambiguous did the ECJ make a
    vague ruling to gauge the reaction of member
    governments? Swift and strong reaction by MGs as
    they were worried by the enormous financial
    implications (H3) of the Barber decision ? treaty
    revision a new restrictive protocol attached to
    the Maastricht Treaty.

14
  • Important remarks
  • in instances where the potential domestic
    ramifications of adverse ECJ decisions are great,
    member governments are unlikely to passively
    abide by Court decisions (consistency with H2).
  • Court decisions with costly domestic
    ramifications for all member governments are
    likely to provoke collective responses to rein in
    the Court (consistency with H3).
  • this is not a game of complete information
    because if it were, the Court would not have
    pushed so hard for an expansive interpretation of
    equal pay, so the Court was not able to
    anticipate the strength of government opposition.
    As precedents were vague, the Court had room to
    modify its interpretations in subsequent
    judgements to accommodate member government
    preferences (consistency with H1).

15
3) State liability for the violation of EU law
  • the problem of transposition of EU directives
    into national laws pre- and post-Maastricht.
  • 1991 Francovich decision the ECJ ruled that
    governments must compensate individuals for the
    loss caused to them resulting from the
    nonimplementation of directives, even those
    without direct effect.
  • The Court has still to establish a system of
    state liability for the violation of EU law.
  • Important remarks
  • The best way to ensure real member government
    compliance with directives was for individuals to
    bring cases against their governments in national
    courts for violations of their rights under EU
    law.
  • Francovich ruling it concerned Italy's failure
    to implement a directive intended to ensure that
    employees received full payments of salary
    arrears if their employers became insolvent. It
    represented a radical change in the Court's
    intervention inside member states.

16
  • How far should state liability go? An extensive
    interpretation would lead to the establishment of
    an EU-wide system of state liability for the
    violation of EU law ? the capstone of the ECJ's
    strategy to expand its influence. How did
    governments react to this threat?
  • Government Responses to Francovich. A strong
    opposition to the expansion of ECJ powers was
    lead by the British Conservatives who put forward
    a proposal establishing that a qualified majority
    in the Council should be able to overturn EJC
    decisions. On the other hand, France and Germany
    attach a positive weight to the existence of an
    effective legal system in Europe (consistency
    with H3).
  • 4) Generally, the political consensus in the EU
    seems to aim at the limitation of Francovich
    ruling. 

17
Toward a system of state liability for the
violation of EU law
  • How should we expect the ECJ to react to this
    political environment? Given that the costs of
    Francovich to all member states are potentially
    enormous (H2, H3) and given that the exact nature
    of the precedent set in the case in unclear (H1),
    we anticipate that in the future the Court will
    voluntarily restrict the application of the state
    liability doctrine in ways desired by the bulk of
    member governments.
  • British Telecommunications and Dillenkofer cases
    the ECJ followed government demands that state
    liability should be a matter of national law,
    subject to a minimum EU standard based on the
    principles governing the liability of EU
    institutions. These cases suggests that the ECJ
    is willing to tailor its state liability rulings
    in ways that the core member governments,
    especially France and Germany, wish.

18
Conclusions
  • ECJ-MGs relationship there is a middle ground to
    analyze it balancing between the legal autonomy
    and political power perspectives.
  • the empirical analysis generates strong support
    for the three hypothesis.
  • the ECJ is manifestly neither master of legal
    integration nor servant of national governments.
  • this framework can be applied also in the context
    of NAFTA and WTO.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com