Alternative approaches to regulation: an economic analysis of lighthanded regulation - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 22
About This Presentation
Title:

Alternative approaches to regulation: an economic analysis of lighthanded regulation

Description:

We want firm-to-firm bargaining to be less than fully efficient ... asymmetries of information on both sides reduce bargaining efficiency ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:42
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 23
Provided by: simon67
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Alternative approaches to regulation: an economic analysis of lighthanded regulation


1
Alternative approaches to regulationan economic
analysis of light-handed regulation
  • Simon Cowan
  • University of Oxford
  • ACCC Regulatory Conference
  • 26-27 July 2007

2
What is light-handed regulation?
  • Formalized in New Zealand for telecoms regulation
  • General competition law
  • Disclosure requirements
  • Threat of subsequent specific regulation
  • For Telecom New Zealand some additional
    constraints on pricing
  • In other versions there is the possibility of
    binding arbitration in the event of disagreement

3
Some theory
  • Three reasons for specific regulation
  • To avoid deadweight losses
  • To promote distributional objectives
  • To encourage relationship-specific investments
  • Asymmetric information and incentives
  • No regulation can be better than standard types
    of regulation
  • Other theoretical examples where regulation gives
    poor outcomes input choices, relative prices
  • The threat of regulation

4
Why regulate?
  • Avoidance of deadweight loss ( unrealized gains
    from trade)
  • But regulation itself has costs
  • It requires specialists (who may be particularly
    costly in developing countries)
  • There are probably economies of scale in
    regulation, so it is more worthwhile in larger
    markets
  • There may also be economies of scope gt
    multi-sector regulation

5
Bargaining instead?
  • The Chicago/Coase question
  • Why dont the firm and its customers bargain to
    realize all the gains from trade, and thus
    eliminate the deadweight loss?
  • Standard counter-argument
  • Customers are typically too small, and too
    numerous, for bargaining to be effective
  • Maybe we can rely on bargaining when the
    customers are themselves large firms
  • Bargaining and distribution regulation to
    allocate the gains from trade?

6
Bargaining and access
  • A network firm bargains with access seekers, but
    no-one bargains with final customers
  • The firms have an incentive to maximize joint
    profits, so bargaining is efficient for the firms
    but not for society
  • We want firm-to-firm bargaining to be less than
    fully efficient
  • The possibility of secret deals (private
    renegotiation) reduces the available profit
  • asymmetries of information on both sides reduce
    bargaining efficiency
  • King and Maddock (1999) threat of binding
    regulation with lower profits, and constraints on
    the bargaining process, can dissipate actual
    profits in equilibrium
  • Overall the argument for bargaining is rather
    delicate either we want it to be perfect for all
    players, or if it is firm-to-firm we want it to
    be less than fully efficient so that joint
    profits are not maximized

7
Regulation as a substitute for long-term contracts
  • There are relationship-specific assets, often on
    both sides, and long-term contracts cannot be
    used
  • A new electricity connection involves
  • (i) wiring in the customers premises
  • (ii) direct connection to the network
  • (iii) network reinforcement (possibly)
  • Typically these costs are shared, with the
    customer paying (i) and (ii) which may be a
    uniform price and the firm paying for (iii)
  • The legislation behind specific regulation, the
    agency tasked with implementing it and the
    judicial framework all provide some stability for
    both sides
  • Such features may be lacking in light-handed
    regimes

8
A model of incentives and efficiency
  • Demand is downward-sloping, so deadweight losses
    can occur
  • Marginal cost is subject to shocks, which are
    private information, and can be reduced by effort
    (which is costly and private)
  • Regulator chooses between three forms of
    regulation rate-of-return, price-cap,
    light-handed

9
The set-up
  • Demand is linear in the price
  • Marginal cost (MC) Cost shock Effort
  • Social welfare Consumer surplus Profits
  • Full information benchmark has price equal
    average cost

10
Three types of regulation
  • Rate of return (ROR) constant margin
  • Price cap (PCR) constant price
  • Light-handed regulation (LHR) no regulation
  • The firm is free to choose its price and effort
    to maximize profits for each cost shock
  • Profit must be non-negative whatever the cost
    shock
  • The aim is to compare expected welfare under the
    three forms of regulation

11
Rate-of-return regulation
  • Price Fixed margin MC
  • Some effort is valuable for the firm if the
    margin is positive it reduces MC, which reduces
    the price, which increases demand, and the firm
    then earns a fixed margin on the extra sales
  • Two offsetting effects of the margin on the
    price
  • Direct effect higher margin raises the price
  • Indirect effect higher margin leads to more
    effort, which cust MC and thus the price
  • These two exactly offset each other Price Cost
    shock
  • Regulator can set the margin optimally to
    maximize expected profits

12
Light-handed regulation
  • The firm chooses price and effort to maximize
    profit in each state
  • Now more effort has an effect on the price
  • The firm exploits its market power
  • But effort cuts MC, which reduces the monopoly
    price
  • The overall effect is that
  • The price with LHR is the same as with ROR
  • LHR dominates ROR in welfare terms, and not just
    on average
  • Why? The firm responds to the cost shock
    optimally under LHR, but will not change its
    effort level under ROR.

13
Price-cap regulation
  • Regulator fixes the price so that average cost in
    the worst state is just covered
  • PCR is fine if there is no asymmetry of
    information (the cost shock is known and
    constant)
  • As the cost shock becomes more variable it
    becomes more likely that rate-of-return
    regulation is better than price-cap, and thus
    that light-handed is better than the price cap

14
The lesson
  • In this model, with restricted regulatory
    options, light-handed regulation is better than
    rate-of-return, and can be better than price-cap
  • Light-handed regulation allows the firm to
    respond to cost shocks
  • With demand shocks such flexibility will usually
    be damaging
  • Well-intentioned regulation can unintended
    consequences
  • But we can always devise even better regulation
  • We could allow something in between full or zero
    passthrough
  • Better than either light-handed or price-cap
    regulation is a combination price ? price-cap

15
Specific regulation can be worse than nothing
  • Averch-Johnson (1962) effect
  • Rate-of-return regulation
  • Allowed rate exceeds the cost of capital
  • Costs are not minimized
  • Avoided if regulation fixes the price and reviews
    are stochastic
  • Price caps and relative prices (Cowan, 1997,
    1998)
  • A tight cap on average revenue can induce the
    firm to set excessive prices in some markets to
    alter the weights in the index and allow prices
    in other markets to rise
  • This can also occur with a regulated price index
    with fixed weights here the problem is
    excessively low prices in some markets
  • In both cases regulation is more likely to be
    worse than no regulation when the level of the
    price cap is low regulation is tough
  • Avoided if price index is of Laspyeres-type
    (weights proportional to quantities and updated
    each period) the tariff basket

16
The threat of regulation
  • Same as a firm choosing its price facing a
    possible fine for anti-trust abuse based on
    excess profits
  • If the probability of regulation (or of
    conviction) does not rise with the price the
    threat of regulation has no effect on pricing
  • The rate of increase of the probability as the
    price rises, as well as the level of the
    probability, matter for deterrence
  • The threat of regulation can achieve some of the
    outcome of direct regulation without the
    associated costs
  • But this doesnt allow for investment decisions

17
New Zealand telecoms
  • Formalized light-handed regulation
  • Problems over access negotiations between Telecom
    and Clear
  • Recent move to specific regulation
  • Interconnection in other countries
  • Split of ATT in 1984 partly because of
    anti-competitive behaviour by ATT towards rivals
  • Pro-competitive determination of access prices
    for Mercury and British Telecom in 1985 in the
    UK, and subsequent direct regulation of access
    terms
  • Local-loop unbundling and broadband access the
    modern version of an old story of interconnection
    controversy
  • Verdict interconnection difficulties were
    predictable, maybe the possibility of binding
    arbitration should have been introduced

18
New Zealand electricity
  • Bertram and Twaddle (Journal of Regulatory
    Economics, 2005) do a careful accounting exercise
    to determine the excess profits earned by
    electricity distribution networks over 1995-2002
  • Average variable costs fell from 1.85 to 1.25
    cents/kWh in real terms
  • Output rose over this period by 18
  • The physical asset stock was largely unchanged
  • Average cost pricing would have normally caused
    prices to fall
  • But average revenue rose from 3.49 to 3.88
    cents/kWh
  • The asset base rose by 3.6 billion, of which
    2.9 billion was due to unilaterally declared
    asset revaluations
  • The authors calculate that there was a 200
    million over-charge each year, compared to what
    would have happened under a standard
    rate-of-return regime

19
Some problems
  • The study uses average revenue, but actual
    tariffs are multi-part, so the rent transfers
    identified need not imply allocative inefficiency
  • The study assumes (a) that the light-touch regime
    could have been replaced by perfect
    rate-of-return regulation that fully extracted
    rents and (b) that there would have been no
    resulting change in firm behaviour (no incentive
    effects)

20
Australian airports
  • Forsyth (2006)
  • Initial tough CPI X price caps for the airports
    once corporatized and privatized (real price
    reductions of 20-25)
  • Tariff-basket used
  • Losses incurred even before the shocks of
    September 2001
  • Replaced by light-touch regulation in 2001/2
  • After a review in 2007 the regime is to continue
    until 2012
  • Deadweight losses probably unimportant, airport
    objectives not only profit-maximization
  • A success story for light-handed regulation?

21
UK gas
  • British Gas was privatized in 1986
  • De facto light-handed regulation but with a
    specific regulator
  • CPI 2 for transportation element of retail
    prices full pass-through of gas purchase costs
  • No regulation of prices to larger customers
  • Weak regulation of access regulator to determine
    price if no agreement
  • No competitive access for five years
  • Subsequent heavy intervention
  • Four investigations by the competition
    authorities (1988, 1991, 1993, 1997) leading to
    vertical separation
  • Tighter retail and access price regulation
  • Initial regulatory framework was unsustainable

22
Conclusions
  • Light-handed regulation has some attractions in
    theory
  • Saves on resource costs, the threat of regulation
    can keep prices low
  • In practice the record is mixed
  • New Zealand has moved away in telecoms and
    electricity
  • But the Australian airports example appears to be
    successful
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com