Global Shocks, Global Financial Crises: How can small open economies like New Zealand protect themse - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 73
About This Presentation
Title:

Global Shocks, Global Financial Crises: How can small open economies like New Zealand protect themse

Description:

Their results from a panel probit show that countries which are open, have lower ... And our panel probit regression evidence shows, in the first era of ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:121
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 74
Provided by: Lew50
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Global Shocks, Global Financial Crises: How can small open economies like New Zealand protect themse


1
Global Shocks, Global Financial CrisesHow can
small open economies like New Zealand protect
themselves? An Historical Perspective
  • Michael D. Bordo
  • Rutgers University
  • National Bureau of Economic Research
  • 2009 Professorial Fellow in Monetary and
    Financial Economics at the Reserve Bank of New
    Zealand and Victoria University

Lecture at Victoria University of Wellington July
16, 2009
2
Global Shocks, Global Financial Crises How can
small open economies like New Zealand protect
themselves? An Historical PerspectiveIntroducti
on
  • The world can be a large and dangerous place for
    a small open economy like New Zealand in the face
    of global shocks.
  • At present we are coming out of just this type of
    event a financial crisis which started with
    subprime mortgages in the U.S., spread through
    derivatives to the global banking system and led
    to a credit crunch and a global recession.
  • The shocks that New Zealand has recently faced in
    an environment of increasing globalization have
    resonance to the first era of globalization in
    the years 1880-1914.
  • Globalization has been associated with an
    increased incidence of financial crises, banking
    crises, debt crises and sudden stops.

3
Introduction
  • With globalization business cycles have become
    increasingly synchronized across countries.
  • They have been connected by common global shocks
    which are often financial.
  • In such an environment a small open economy can
    be hit hard by financial crises leading to
    recessions.
  • It can also be hit by real shocks that reduce the
    terms of trade and the volume of its exports.
  • What factors can prevent global shocks from being
    so damaging?

4
Introduction
  • This lecture provides summary evidence for a
    panel of countries from 1880 to the present on
    the incidence of various types of financial
    crises and on the international synchronization
    of business cycles.
  • It then summarizes evidence on the determinants
    of various types of crises.
  • Based on this research we can isolate variables
    that can attenuate the impact of shocks. These
    include macro fundamentals and institutional
    variables.
  • We then turn to the case of New Zealand. We
    consider how it fared within the historical
    context of global financial crises.
  • The record suggests that New Zealand did quite
    well in avoiding serious financial stress as did
    other countries with sound institutions and
    policies.

5
Introduction
  • Unlike financial crises, New Zealand has been
    significantly affected by global real shocks,
    especially terms of trade shocks and declines in
    exports consequent upon foreign recessions.
  • In reaction to the massive global shocks in the
    1930s, New Zealand shifted to a policy of
    insulationism, instigating a wide range of
    controls within the context of the Bretton Woods
    pegged exchange rate regime.
  • This approach may have provided some insulation
    but at the expense of a slower growth rate.
  • Many of the controls were rolled back in the mid
    1980s along with the abandonment of pegged
    exchange rates.
  • The subsequent liberalized financial regime with
    floating exchange rates exposed New Zealand again
    to global financial shocks but the floating
    exchange rates may have provided some insulation
    from their real effects.

6
Road Map
  • Introduction
  • Some facts on crises and the international
    synchronization of business cycles
  • Evidence on the determinants of crises for 30
    countries
  • New Zealands experience with crises
  • New Zealands experience with global real shocks
  • Policy lessons

7
2. Some facts on crises2.1 Banking and Currency
Crisis 1880 to 1997
  • As background I present evidence on the incidence
    of financial crises.
  • Bordo, Eichengreen, Kliengebiel, and
    Martinez-Peria(2001), provide evidence for a
    panel of 21 countries for 120 years and 56
    countries for the 4 recent decades on the
    frequency, duration and severity of currency,
    banking and twin crises across 4 policy regimes.
  • We compare output losses and recovery times in
    crises with their counterparts in recessions
    where no crises occurred.
  • We define financial crises as episodes of
    financial turbulence leading to distress
    significant problems of illiquidity and
    insolvencyamong major financial market
    participants and/or to official intervention to
    contain those consequences.

8
2. Some facts on crises2.1 Banking and Currency
Crises 1880 to 1997
  • We identified currency crisis dates using an
    exchange market pressure measure and,
    alternatively, survey of expert opinion. We use
    the union of these indicators and an EMP cutoff
    of 1.5 standard deviations from the mean.
  • For banking crises, we adopted World Bank dates
    for post-1971 period, and used similar criteria
    (bank runs, bank failures, and suspensions of
    convertibility, fiscal resolution) for earlier
    periods.
  • Twin crises banking and currency crises in same
    or consecutive years. Crises in consecutive years
    counted as one event.

9
  • We distinguish four periods
  • 1880-1914 prior period of financial
    liberalization and globalization
  • 1919-1939 period of exceptional currency,
    banking and macro instability
  • 1945-1971 Bretton Woods period of tight
    regulation of domestic financial systems and of
    capital controls
  • 1973-1998 second period of financial
    liberalization and globalization

10
  • Frequency of Crises
  • We divide the number of crises by the number of
    country year observations in each sub-period.
    (See Figure 1.)
  • Alarmingly, all crises appear to be growing more
    frequent.
  • Crisis frequency of 12.2 since 1973 exceeds even
    the unstable interwar period and is three times
    as great as the pre 1914 earlier era of
    globalization.
  • Results driven by currency crises, which have
    become much more frequent in recent period.
  • This challenges the notion that financial
    globalization creates instability in foreign
    exchange markets since pre 1914 was the earlier
    era of globalization.
  • May be due to a combination of capital mobility
    and democratization.

11
Figure 1 Crisis Frequency (per cent probability
per year)
12
  • Frequency of Crises
  • In contrast, incidence of banking crises only
    slightly larger than prior to 1914, while twin
    crises more frequent in the late twentieth
    century.
  • Note that interwar period had highest incidence
    of banking crises.
  • Bretton Woods period was notable for the absence
    of banking crises due to financial repression.
  • A comparison of crisis frequency between emerging
    and industrial countries (see Figure 2), suggests
    that with the exception of the interwar period,
    the majority of crises occurred in the emerging
    countries.

13
Figure 2 Frequency of Crises Distribution by
Market
14
  • Duration of Crises
  • We define the duration of crises as the average
    recovery time. The number of years before the
    rate of GDP growth returns to its 5-year trend
    preceding the crisis. (See Table 1.)
  • Recovery time today for currency crises is longer
    than preceding 2 regimes but shorter than pre
    1914.
  • Banking crises last not much longer now than in
    earlier periods.
  • Recent period twin crises produce the longest
    slump for emerging markets.
  • The dominant impression from comparison of pre
    1914 and today for all crises is how little has
    changed.
  • To the extent that crises have been growing
    longer, we have simply been going back to the
    future.

15
Table 1 Duration and Depth of Crises
16
  • Depth of Crises
  • We calculate the depth of crises by calculating,
    over the years prior to full recovery, the
    difference between pre-crisis trend growth and
    actual growth. (See Table 1 which shows
    cumulative output loss as a percentage of GDP.)
  • We find that output losses from currency crises
    were even greater before 1914 than today. The
    difference is most pronounced for emerging
    countries.
  • Output losses from banking crises also greater in
    pre 1914 regime than today.
  • Twin crises show comparable output losses for
    today and pre-1914 for emerging markets.
  • Key unsurprising fact is the large output losses
    in the interwar from both currency and twin
    crises.

17
  • 2.2 Evidence on Debt Crises and Sudden Stops
  • I have extended the historical comparisons to
    include Debt Crises (18801913 versus 1972-1997)
    (Bordo and Meissner 2006) and Sudden Stops
    (1880-1913 versus 1980-2004) (Bordo, Cavallo, and
    Meissner 2009). See Figures 3 and 4.
  • In terms of output losses, sudden stops were less
    serious than other crises but when combined with
    other financial crises the results are dramatic.
  • Sudden stops associated with crises produced 10
    to 12 times greater collapses in growth than
    those not associated with crises. See Table 2.

18
Figure 3 Crisis Frequency in Percentage
Probability per Year 1880-1913 vs. 1972-1997
19
Figure 4 Frequency of Different Types of Crises
1880-1913 In percent probability per year
20
Table 2 Sudden Stops and Financial Crises
21
  • 2.3 Evidence on Contagion
  • Contagion refers to the bunching of crises in
    several countries.
  • See Figures 5 and 6 which show the countries
    affected by crises in the same year from the
    sample of countries in Bordo et al (2001).

22
Figure 5 Countries Affected by Crises From a
Sample of 21 Countries, 1880-1914 Source Bordo
and Eichengreen (1999)
23
Figure 6 Countries Affected by Crises From a
Sample of 21 Countries, 1919-1939 Source Bordo
and Eichengreen (1999)
24
  • Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff (2008) have
    extended the data base of financial crises in
    Bordo et al (2001) to include many more
    countries, to include episodes back to 1800 and
    forward to 2008.
  • The incidence of banking crises they show in
    Figure 7 (the proportion of countries with crises
    weighted by their shares of income) presents a
    pattern for banking crises which echoes that in
    Bordo et al (2001), with the highest incidence in
    the interwar and a recurrence of crises since the
    early 1970s.
  • The recent episode promises to be as severe as
    the crises of the 1990s.

25
Figure 7 Proportion of Countries with Banking
Crises, 1900-2008 Weighted by Their Share of
World Income
26
  • 2.4 Evidence on the Synchronization of Business
    Cycles
  • Bordo and Helbling (2009) find that
    synchronization based on bilateral correlations
    for log output growth shows higher positive
    correlation coefficients across the four exchange
    rate regimes. See Figure 8.

27
Figure 8 Bilateral Output Correlation
Coefficients by Percentile
28
  • 2.4 Evidence on the Synchronization of Business
    Cycles
  • This pattern is largely driven by a sequence of
    global shocks that occur during periods of
    worldwide downturns. See Figure 9.

29
  • Figure 9 Global Shocks, 1887-2008

30
  • Figure 9 Global Shocks, 1887-2008

31
  • 2.4 Evidence on the Synchronization of Business
    Cycles
  • These common shocks are related to a global
    financial conditions index based on the first
    principal components of a cross-section of
    financial indicators. See Figure 10.

32
  • Figure 10 Global Financial and GDP Shocks,
    1887-2001

33
  • Figure 10 Global Financial and GDP Shocks,
    1887-2001

34
  • 3. The Determinants of Crises
  • 3.1 A Framework linking Integration to Crises and
    Crises to Growth
  • Our framework for thinking about financial crises
    follows Mishkin (2003) and Jeanne and Zettelmeyer
    (2005). This view follows an open-economy
    approach to the credit channel transmission
    mechanism of monetary policy.
  • Balance sheets, net worth and informational
    asymmetries are key ingredients in this type of a
    framework.
  • See Figure 11.

35
  • Figure 11 A Crisis Framework

36
  • The Chain of Logic Crises
  • Real shocks (rise in international interest
    rates) transmit into the Banking system.
  • Worsens banking sheets. Reduces lending.
  • Capital Flows Reverse.
  • Reserves decline/currency crisis or devaluation.
  • Crisis could be prevented with LLR, financial
    depth, credible peg, fiscal probity.
  • Sudden stops or devaluation could adversely
    affect balance sheets if original sin present.

37
  • The Chain of Logic Crises
  • Scenario worse if country is financially
    fragile/underdeveloped.
  • Depends on the currency mismatch.
  • Possibility of debt crisis and default depends in
    part on fiscal control and political system.
  • Accordingly to Kohlcheen (2006) presidential
    democracies were more likely to default than
    parliamentary democracies.

38
  • Evidence
  • 3.2 Sudden Stops
  • Bordo, Cavallo and Meissner (2009) find evidence
    on the determinants of sudden stops 1880-1913 for
    30 countries including New Zealand. Their
    results are similar to those of Calvo et al
    (2004) for the recent period.
  • Their results from a panel probit show that
    countries which are open, have lower levels of
    original sin (hard currency debt relative to
    total debt) and have strong fundamentals have
    lower probabilities of being hit by a sudden
    stop.
  • They also found based on a treatments effects
    growth regression that sudden stops reduces
    growth by close to 5 from the long-run average
    growth rate.
  • Sudden stops that accompany financial crises
    reduce growth considerably.

39
  • 3.3 Currency Crises
  • Bordo and Meissner (2009) using a panel probit
    for 30 countries (including New Zealand)
    1880-1913 find that a large positive change in
    the current account to GDP and low levels of
    reserves to notes are associated with high
    probabilities of a currency crisis.
  • Currency crises were driven by current account
    reversals and sudden stops.
  • High levels of original sin and a low foreign
    currency debt mismatch also lead to currency
    crises.
  • For the 1972-2003 period results are similar.

40
  • 3.4 Banking Crises
  • Bordo and Meissner (2005) find that a key
    determinant of banking crises 1880-1913 was
    original sin.
  • But countries with a high level of original sin
    like the British dominions and Scandinavia have a
    low probability of banking crises.
  • Countries like Argentina and Italy with a
    moderate amount of original sin were crisis
    prone.
  • The key difference between the two groups of
    countries is poorer fundamentals and lower
    financial development . Also the risk of crisis
    is offset by having sufficient hard currency
    assets to match hard currency liabilities.
  • For the 1972-97 period Bordo and Meissner (2006)
    find that original sin and a high mismatch is
    associated with a greater chance of a banking
    crisis but that countries with higher income can
    avoid crises.

41
  • 3.5 Debt Crises
  • The likelihood of debt crises in both eras of
    globalization increases significantly with the
    level of foreign currency debt exposures but in
    the pre 1914 era countries with sound
    fundamentals like the British dominions were less
    exposed.
  • Institutional factors include a low level of
    currency mismatch, adherence to the gold
    standard, and being a Parliamentary democracy.

42
  • 3.6 The Bottom Line
  • Debtor countries with sound fundamentals and
    institutions could avoid financial crises.
  • In the first era of globalization countries like
    the British dominions, Sweden and Denmark with
    very high ratios of foreign currency debt to
    total debt could avoid crises by having high
    export receipts in foreign currency or large
    international reserves.
  • They also had country trust (Caballero Cowan
    and Kearns 2006) based on sound institutions, the
    rule of law and stable political systems.
  • Key institutional factors were the commitment and
    ability to maintain adherence to the gold
    standard in the British dominions. For example,
    New Zealand banks held large sterling asset
    positions in London. Many dominion debt issues
    had the guarantee of the British government.

43
  • 3.6 The Bottom Line
  • By contrast other countries like those in Latin
    America and Southern and Eastern Europe that
    embraced global financial flows but did not
    adequately fortify their financial systems faced
    severe financial crises enveloping the banking
    system, the currency and the national debt.
  • In the recent era high per capita income
    countries with high original sin like New Zealand
    have limited exposure to capital account crises.
  • The countries most exposed to such crises were
    middle income emerging countries with high
    original sin. Their fragility to current account
    reversals and crises was evident in the 1990s.
  • Today countries like Iceland, the Baltics and
    some eastern European countries are in the same
    boat.

44
  • 4. New Zealand Financial Crises
  • New Zealand has had a relatively benign crisis
    experience.
  • Table 3 contains a chronology of New Zealands
    financial crises.
  • New Zealand experienced 2 banking crises, 7
    currency crises, 8 sudden stops, no debt crises
    or twin crises.

45
  • 4. New Zealand Financial Crises
  • Table 3 A Chronology of New Zealand Crises
  • SS1 in bold

46
  • 4.1 Banking Crises
  • First banking crisis 1890-95 involved Bank of New
    Zealand.
  • Crisis triggered by a land boom which collapsed
    in the mid 1880s. Causes include a decline in
    wool prices, a sudden stop engineered by the Bank
    of England, the Baring crisis of 1890 and the
    Australian crisis of 1893.
  • The BNZ financed and owned much of NZ mortgages.
  • The BNZ was recapitalized by the government in
    July 1895.
  • The cost of the bailout was 1.6 of GDP which was
    a small fraction of Australias cost.

47
  • Banking Crises
  • Second banking crisis 1987 to 1990 also involved
    the BNZ and a property boom consequent upon
    financial deregulation after 1984.
  • The bust followed the October 1987 Wall Street
    crash which led to sharp drops in NZ equities.
  • The BNZ was recapitalized in 1990 at a cost of 1
    of GDP.

48
  • 4.2 Currency Crises
  • We identify currency crises based on an EMP index
    supplemented with historical narrative. New
    Zealand had 7 currency crises which occurred
    during pegged exchange rate regimes.
  • The crises of 1931 and 1933 occurred as a
    consequence of the 1937-38 recession. It led to
    the imposition of a strict exchange control and
    import licensing regime.
  • NZ joined the IMF in 1961. The crisis of 1967
    followed the collapse of the wool market in 1966
    which caused deterioration in the current account
    and a depletion of New Zealands reserves. NZ
    devalued by 19.45 following sterlings
    devaluation in November.
  • The 2 oil price shocks of the 1970s led to crises
    in 1974-74 and 1979. Each led to devaluations.
  • The last crisis was in 1984 following
    deregulation of the financial sector and the
    elimination of exchange and capital controls, the
    NZ dollar was devalued by 20.

49
  • 4.3 Sudden Stops
  • We measure sudden stops by a sharp drop in net
    capital inflow accompanied by a drop in real GDP
    (SS1) and (SS2) measured as a large decline in
    net capital inflows regardless of the impact on
    output.
  • Sudden stops preceded the 1890s banking crisis,
    the 1930s crises and the 1970s crises.
  • Sudden stops in 1997/98 and 2008/09 did not lead
    to crises in New Zealand.

50
  • 4.4 Some Evidence for New Zealand from Pooled
    Probit Regressions
  • Using cross country regression models for the two
    eras of globalization Mizhuo Kida of the RBNZ and
    I ascertain the variables which made New Zealand
    more or less vulnerable than the average
    countries in the Bordo, Meissner sample to the
    risks of being hit by currency crises and sudden
    stops.
  • Figure 12 shows the predicted probabilities of
    having a currency crisis in New Zealand versus
    the average country 1880 1913.

51
(No Transcript)
52
  • 4.4 Some Evidence for New Zealand from Pooled
    Probit Regressions
  • New Zealand performed better in avoiding currency
    crises by maintaining a large trade surplus and
    having positive terms of trade shocks which
    offset its relative vulnerabilities from having a
    relatively large hard currency mismatch.
  • Figure 13 shows that in the first era of
    globalization New Zealand was slightly more
    vulnerable to having a sudden stop (SS1) than
    average because it had higher original sin and
    slightly lower gold reserves on average.

53
(No Transcript)
54
  • 4.4 Some Evidence for New Zealand from Pooled
    Probit Regressions
  • For the recent period of globalization 1972
    1992, when New Zealand had three currency crises,
    Figure 14 shows that New Zealand had a somewhat
    higher risk of a currency crisis than others
    because it had a higher mismatch, higher debt
    relative to GDP, higher long term interest rates
    and lower reserves.
  • These effects were not fully offset by its high
    per capita income (as a proxy for a better set of
    institutions, more developed financial system
    and/or better management of debt).
  • However, what differentiated New Zealand from
    other countries which suffered more frequent
    currency crisis in the recent period was its
    relatively high per capita real income and the
    characteristics that goes with it.

55
(No Transcript)
56
  • 4.4 Some Evidence for New Zealand from Pooled
    Probit Regressions
  • Thus New Zealand was less exposed to the risks of
    a currency crisis than the average in the first
    era of globalisation because of its better
    fundamentals but this was not the case in the
    second era.
  • Moreover, in the 1880 1913 period New Zealand
    was vulnerable to sudden stops because of its
    high level of original sin.

57
  • 4.5 Insulationism
  • In reaction to the Great Depression New Zealand
    followed a policy of insulationism to protect the
    economy from the vagaries of the global economy.
    (Singleton 2008, Hawke 1985).
  • The goals were to maintain full employment,
    develop manufacturing and suppress imports while
    maintaining exports, and remaining on the
    sterling peg.
  • Policies followed included import licensing, high
    tariffs and financial controls like interest rate
    ceilings.
  • The regime maintained full employment through the
    1960s and fostered an inefficient manufacturing
    industry.
  • NZ was hit by the external shocks of the 1970s
    leading to currency crises and recession.

58
  • 4.5 Insulationism
  • Increasing evidence of relatively poor growth
    performance led to the end of import controls and
    deregulation of the financial sector as well as
    adoption of a floating exchange rate in 1984.
  • A credible nominal anchor was instituted in 1989,
    with the RBNZ getting operational independence
    and focusing on price stability.
  • Did the policy of insulationism really achieve
    the goal of protecting New Zealand from outside
    shocks or did it weaken NZ sufficiently to make
    it more vulnerable to the bigger shocks that
    followed in the 1970s?
  • To answer this question requires a counterfactual
    exercise to ascertain whether alternative
    arrangements such as shifting earlier to a regime
    of floating exchange rates, without the extensive
    controls, would have done a better job.

59
  • 5. Real Shocks and the New Zealand Economy
  • Using annual macroeconomic data from 1880 to the
    present David Hargreaves of the RBNZ and I
    investigate the impact of international variables
    on the New Zealand real economy.
  • In a benchmark regression we regressed a three
    year moving average growth rate of real NZ per
    capita income on the terms of trade the real
    sterling exchange rate and U.S. real GDP. (See
    table 4, column 1).

60
  • 5. Real Shocks and the New Zealand Economy
  • Table 4 Regression of NZ growth of real per
    capita GDP on key drivers of growth

61
  • 5. Real Shocks and the New Zealand Economy Cont..
  • Real U.S. output, the terms of trade and the real
    exchange rate are statistically significant and
    have reasonable signs.
  • In column 2 of the table we added indicators of
    financial crises to the regression. Both
    indicators of currency crises and sudden steps
    were not statistically significant.
  • The two long periods of banking crises have a
    negative impact on growth although the
    coefficient is not precisely estimated or
    significant. The coefficient is consistent with
    a four year banking crisis reducing output by
    about 2.5 percentage points.
  • A measure of variability in capital inflows
    comparable to the SS2 sudden stop indicator is
    significant. This suggests that slowing or
    reversals of capital controls are deleterious for
    growth.

62
  • 5. Real Shocks and the New Zealand Economy Cont..
  • Figure 15 shows the impact of all the regressors
    in the benchmark regression (yellow line)
    compared to the actual variable (blue line).
  • Figure 15 NZ growth and effects of key
    driving variables

63
  • 5. Real Shocks and the New Zealand Economy Cont..
  • U.S. growth and the terms of trade explain much
    of the variation in growth with the exception of
    the second half of the 1920s and after the
    depression. The latter anomaly may partly relate
    to the imposition of controls in 1938 and the
    subsequent shift to wartime production.

64
  • 5. Real Shocks and the New Zealand Economy Cont..
  • Figure 16 adds in the crisis variables. The
    impact of the two banking crises is evident in
    the 1890s and 1990s.
  • Figure 16 NZ growth with banking crisis and
    capital flow effects

65
  • 5. Real Shocks and the New Zealand Economy Cont..
  • Finally we tested whether there was evidence of
    instability over time in the coefficients of
    global growth and the terms of trade using a
    recursive regression and a Kalman filter. See
    figure 17.
  • Figure 17 Variation in coefficients on key
    driving variables

66
  • 5. Real Shocks and the New Zealand Economy Cont..
  • The variability of external factors was reduced
    after 1938.
  • This could reflect both the extensive controls
    imposed between 1938 and 1984 (shaded in blue)
    and the use of floating exchange rates as an
    economic buffer post 1984.
  • It is difficult to see much of a difference in
    the coefficients of the three variables between
    the 1938 84 period and the subsequent float.
  • This could suggest that the costs of the economic
    distortions in the controls regime may have been
    avoided if New Zealand had turned to a more
    liberal regime with floating earlier, as for
    example Canada did in 1950.

67
  • 5.1 The Bottom Line
  • Financial crises do not appear to have additional
    strong explanatory power once the impact of key
    global variables is accounted for.
  • This may reflect the mild nature of many of the
    crises in New Zealand history.
  • These results suggests that avoiding banking and
    currency crises will not be sufficient to avoid
    the domestic economic impact of major disruptions
    to the global business cycle.
  • The bottom line is that it is not difficult to
    find strong evidence that New Zealand has been
    crucially influenced by global factors.

68
  • 5.1 The Bottom Line cont..
  • Shocks to the terms of trade, foreign growth, the
    real exchange rate and capital inflows all
    impacted on NZ growth.
  • Similar factors have been at work in the recent
    past.

69
  • 6. Conclusions and lessons for Policy
  • Our historical research suggests that financial
    crises are often associated with globalisation.
  • Countries can avoid financial crises by following
    sound policies and adopting sound institutions.
  • Having sound polices and institutions certainly
    helped the British dominions, the advanced
    countries, and some emerging countries, avoid
    crises in the first era of globalisation.
  • And our panel probit regression evidence shows,
    in the first era of globalization that New
    Zealands predicted probability of having a
    currency crisis was somewhat lower than the
    average country.
  • Having sound policies and institutions helped
    avoid crises for some emergers and small open
    advanced countries in the current era of
    globalisation.

70
  • 6. Conclusions and lessons for Policy
  • However, for the recent period New Zealand,
    despite its higher per capita income as a proxy
    for sound institutions, was somewhat more
    vulnerable to a currency crisis than the average
    country.
  • Moreover, real shocks can have serious real
    effects on small open economies like New Zealand
    which follow basically sound policies and have
    solid institutions.
  • The evidence in this lecture suggests that shocks
    to U.S. real GDP as a proxy for global output and
    shocks to the terms of trade have material and
    significant effects on New Zealands growth.

71
  • 6. Conclusions and lessons for Policy cont..
  • The worst example was the Great Depression of the
    1930s but New Zealand was also hit by the shock
    of Britain joining the European common market in
    1973, the oil price shocks of the 1970s, the
    U.S. stock market crash of 1987 and the recent
    U.S. mortgage crisis.
  • In reaction to global shocks New Zealand shifted
    to a policy of insulationism in the late 1930s.
  • The subsequent controls regime did succeed in
    battening down the hatches for 4 decades and may
    have provided shelter from foreign winds.
  • But at the cost of economic inefficiency and
    relatively slow growth.

72
  • 6. Conclusions and lessons for Policy cont..
  • Since 1984 the controls regime has been
    dismantled and NZ has shifted to a floating
    exchange rate and credible fiscal and monetary
    policy.
  • Evidence for Canada since 1950 and many other
    countries since 1973 suggests that a floating
    exchange rate is the best insulation against
    foreign shocks.
  • But floating can create problems of its own for
    a small open economy.
  • An alternative for New Zealand could be a
    monetary union with Australia but taking such a
    step would remove the ability to use domestic
    monetary policy to offset asymmetric shocks.

73
  • 6. Conclusions and lessons for Policy cont..
  • The jury is still out on EMU as providing more
    effective insulation against asymmetric shocks
    versus what would have been the case if the
    individual European countries had their own
    currencies.
  • But the benefits of increased integration for a
    monetary union are not insignificant.
  • This is an issue that will continue to be debated
    for years to come.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com