Karl Marx: Heracles or Sisyphus - a Philosophic and Economic Interpretation Expert Mission October 27th to November 12th GIZ, Beijing - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 100
About This Presentation
Title:

Karl Marx: Heracles or Sisyphus - a Philosophic and Economic Interpretation Expert Mission October 27th to November 12th GIZ, Beijing

Description:

Karl Marx: Heracles or Sisyphus - a Philosophic and Economic Interpretation Expert Mission October 27th to November 12th GIZ, Beijing * Prof. Dr. Malte Faber ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:1428
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 101
Provided by: Friedric3
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Karl Marx: Heracles or Sisyphus - a Philosophic and Economic Interpretation Expert Mission October 27th to November 12th GIZ, Beijing


1
Karl Marx Heracles or Sisyphus- a Philosophic
and Economic InterpretationExpert
MissionOctober 27th to November 12thGIZ, Beijing
2
Reminder
  • This lecture is based on a joint paper
  • Karl Marx Heracles or Sisyphus, Discussion
    Paper, Department of Economics, University of
    Heidelberg, October 2011.by the
  • philosopher Thomas Petersen Department of
    Philosophy, and
  • the economist Malte Faber Department of
    Economics.

3
Heracles and Sisyphos
  • Heracles and Sisyphos were both mythic figures.
  • Heracles was the sun of Zeus and he is known for
    having fullfilled 12 extroadinary difficult
    tasks.
  • Sisyphos was compelled to roll an immense boulder
    up a hill, only to watch it roll back down, and
    to repeat this throughout eternity.

4
Table of Contents
  • 0. Summary
  • Introduction
  • Marx and Hegel
  • Basics of Marx Economic Theory
  • Historical Materialism
  • Analysis of the Capitalistic Method of Production
  • 5.1. Simple Reproduction
  • 5.2. Basics of the Extended Reproduction
  • 5.3. Capitalistic Society and Justice
  • 5.4. The Real Capitalistic Exploitation
    Process the Production
  • 6. Marx as Scientific Economist

5
(No Transcript)
6
Table of Contents
  • 6. Marx as Scientific Economist
  • 6.1. Labour Theory of Value and the
    Transformation Problem
  • 6.2. The Law of the Falling Rate of Profit
  • 6.3. Joint Production and its Repercussions on
  • the Environment
  • 6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
  • and the thereby effected Environmental and
    Resource
  • Problems
  • 6.5. Marx and the Socialism
  • 6.6. Concluding Remarks

7
Table of Contents
  • 7. Labour Theory of Value, Theory of the State
    and Income
  • Distribution
  • 7.1. Theory of the State
  • 7.2. Income Distribution
  • 8. Summary
  • Literature

8
Summary
  • During the last decades a new kind of debate
    concerning the work of Marx (1818-1883) has
    developed, which is much less ideological.
  • Marxists and Nonmarxist have found a common
    language to discuss Marxian matters.
  • Nevertehless there exists one deficit
    philosophers and economists do not talk to each
    other.

9
Summary
  • A case in point is the role of the philosopher
  • Friedrich Wilhelm Hegel (1770-1731) in Marx
    thinking.
  • While
  • philosophers emphasize Hegels role,
  • economists tend to neglect it.
  • We shall show that Marxs relationship to Hegel
    is
  • central for his theory in general and
  • for his economic theory in particular.

10
Summary
  • The main task of this lecture is to give
  • an overall appraisal of Marx work and
  • thus to cut through ist numerous ambiguities.
  • In detail we represent
  • its relationship to Hegel and the historical
    materialism
  • main statements of Marxian Economics are in
    respect to modern economic theory discussed.

11
Summary
  • Characteristic of the dynamics of the
    capitalistic system represented
  • Essential insights concerning present
    environmental and resource problems are
    explained.
  • Implications for justice and the income
    distribution are highlighted.
  • Finally, the notorious deficit of Marxtheory of
    politics is commneted.

12
1. Introduction
  • To understand the
  • Work of Marx is for various reasons difficult.
  • His stupendous ability to apply philosophical
    methods to economics. Thus one does not know
    wheter the first chapters of the 1. volume of the
    Capital is a philosophical or economic text.
  • One never knows whether one is confronted with a
    scientific analysis of modern economy or a
    philosphical description as is offered by Hegel.
  • His connection of cool scientific analysis and
    religiously coloured political agitation.scientifi
    c his manner to connect scientific analysis with
    prophecy.

13
1. Introduction
  • His promosing first, a system of ultimate ends
    that embody the meaning of life and absolute
    standards by which to judge events and actions
    and secondly, a (scientific, M.F.) guide to those
    which implies a plan for salvation (Schumpeter
    1980 19).
  • His promise of a scientific socialism.
  • Marx employed an individualistic,
    functionalistic and holistic approaches.

14
1. Introduction
  • As Elster (986 103) noted concerning Marx
    perception of history Marx had both an
    empirical theory of history and a speculative
    philosophy of history.. Hence the reader does not
    know whether the Marxian historical materialism
    is an analytical theory of history or rather a
    version of world history as salvific history
    (Löwith 1979)
  • It is something completely new the
    transformation of philosophy and economics.
  • The philosophers have only interpreted the
    world, in various ways the point is to change
    it (Marx, MEW3, 7, Theses on Feuerbach)

15
1. Introduction
  • According to Marx this change of the world has
    to occur in economic terms, because the
    fundamental structure of the social world is
    economic.
  • This implies one has first to pursue economic
    research.
  • For this reason Marx considered himself not to be
    a philosopher but a political economist.
  • Hence, his main work, his magnum opus, Capital,
    was a contribution to Political Economy.
  • Thus, economics became an executor of the last
    will of philosophy.

16
1. Introduction
  • What aims did Marx pursue?
  • He wanted to develop a uniformly social science,
    into which philosphy was transformed.
  • He wanted to revolutionize society.
  • Both aims have something Herculian
  • A new theory of economics, which contains
    essential elements of practical philosophy,
  • a sociological theory of
  • classes,
  • knowledge and
  • consciousness
  • as well as a concept of ideology.

17
1. Introduction
  • But his efforts often seem rather in vain this
    can perhaps be
  • best recognized in his economic work, where he
    once and again attempts to d evelop a theory of
    prices on the basis of labour values.
  • This makes Marx less Hercules but rather
    Sisyphos.
  • In addtion, much of his work is rather sketchy.
    Even well minde interpreters of his work like
  • Jon Elster and
  • John Roemer (19988 2)
  • Joseph A. Schumpeter
  • their dismay concerning his lack of
    argumentatiove consistency.

18
1. Introduction
  • Marxs intellectual energy was not matched by a
    comparable level of intellectual discipline. His
    intellectual profile is a complex blend of
    relentless search for truth, wishful thinking,
    and polemic intent (Elster 1986 2).
  • As always when reading Marx, one is struck by
    admiration for the brilliance of his intellect
    and dumbfounded by his lack for consistency.
    (ibid. 138)
  • His utopian attitude and lack of intellectual
    control prevented him from carrying out the
    theoretical and practical tasks he had set for
    himself, but without theses qualities he would
    not even have tried. He suffered the cost we are
    the beneficiaries. (ibid. 200)

19
1. Introduction
in order to forge such weapons for the arena of
social strife Marx had to occasionally to bend or
to deviate from, the opinions that would
logically follow from his system.(Schumpeter
1980 21) Marx also often wakened expectations
which he did not fulfil. Desais quote on the
Marxian paper A Contribution to the Critique of
Hegels Philosophy of Right applies also to many
other other attempts
20
1. Introduction
Marx also often called up expectations which he
did not fulfil. Desais quote on the Marxian
paper A Contribution to the Critique of Hegels
Philosophy of Right applies also to many other
other attempts
21
1. Introduction
  • On his marriage to Jenny von Westphalia, he
    managed to write his first major work, but like
    many of his other works, it was unpublished in
    his lifetime a critique of Hegels Philosophy of
    Right, the Masters last complete publication. It
    is a fragment, but Marx had promised his friends
    an earth-shattering critique of Hegel that would
    settle scores once and for all. And as often in
    his later life, he promised more than he could
    deliver.
  • Thus Marx picture alternates in history.
  • But we should not forget Elsters remark Marx
    suffered the cost we are the beneficiaries.

22
2. Marx and Hegel
  • There exists one serious deficit in the modern
    presentation of the Marxian work.
  • The reason is
  • Philosophers and economists do not talk to each
    other.

23
2. Marx an Hegel
  • A case in point is the role of the philosopher
  • Friedrich Wilhelm Hegel (1770-1731) in Marx
    thinking.
  • While
  • philosophers emphasize Hegels role,
  • economists tend to neglect it.
  • We shall show that Marxs relationship to Hegel
    is
  • central for his theory in general and
  • for his economic theory in particular.

24
2. Marx and Hegel
  • We explain
  • the influence of Hegel on Marx,
  • Marx's position concerning the young Hegelians
    (Junghegelianer) and
  • how he differs from Marx.

25
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory
  • Basics of Marxs economic theory are sketched in
    this section.
  • He delivers a critique of political economy,
  • but at the same time he wants to give an
    explicative theory of the modern economy,
  • which together stands in the service of
    revolutionizing the world.

26
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory
  • Difficulty
  • One never knows when dealing with the economist
    Marx whether he is
  • a scientist
  • a political agitator or finally only a
  • a philosopher, who has erred into fields which
    are align to him.

27
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory
  • Marx contributed little concretely to a theory of
    socialism.
  • He did not understand himself as a theoretician
    of socialism, but rather as
  • a critic and
  • analyst
  • of the capitalistic system.
  • His attempt to surpass the bourgeois economic
    theory by a superior one failed. The main reason
    for this failure was his inadequate instrument,
    the theory of value.

28
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory
  • Labor theory of value the value of a good, which
    is exchanged as a commodity, is determined by its
    labor value.
  • Marx learned this approach from one of the great
    classical economists, David Riccardo (1772-1823).
  • In contrast to Ricardo, Marx applied this theory
    also to labor itself, insofar as the capability
    to create value.

29
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory
  • Marx
  • The value of labor is equal to the labor value
    which is necessary for the reproduction of labor
    (i.e. all the goods which a labor needs to
    reproduce himself and his family, in particular
    his off springs).
  • The value of goods is higher than the labor value
    necessary to produce it.
  • The difference is called surplus value.

30
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory
  • Buying the manpower of a laborer and
  • using it for his purpose the entrepreneur
    acquires the surplus value in form of profits
  • The problem of this value analysis is, that
    profit can only be realized
  • in an exchange economy
  • in which prices are paid.

31
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory
  • The value is an inner quality of the commodity
  • The price is an externally recognizable
    information.
  • Marx has to assert that the value determines the
    price.
  • As will be shown in section 6.1 below.
  • This statement is true only
  • under very restrictive conditions
  • which in reality never hold.

32
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory
  • Marx has attempted in the third volume of Capital
    which was published by Friedrich Engels only
    after his death to solve, or perhaps correctly
    said, to conceal it.
  • This endeavor has lead
  • to many ambiguities and
  • great confusion and
  • extremely complicated the understanding of his
    work.
  • As shown in section 5 and 6 below, this
    contradiction cannot be solved.

33
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory
Conclusion Marx theoretical approach is not
suited to give a quantitative analysis of the
economy and a scientifically satisfying
description of the economy. While the disparity
between value analysis and price theory and Marx
attempts to cover the tension between the two of
them, the lecture of his texts vary cumbersome
matters get even more complicated by an actually
ambiguity of Marx concept of value or as Petry
(1916 28) said by the Janus face of the Marxian
theory of value.
34
3. Basics of Marx Economic Theory

35
4. Historical Materialism
  • Marxs And Engels ,materialistic conception of
    history or historical materialism is outlined.
  • Central concepts are
  • forces of production
  • relations of production
  • mode of production.

36
4. Historical Materialism
  • Marxs And Engels ,materialistic conception of
    history or historical materialism is outlined.
  • Central concepts are
  • forces of production
  • relations of production
  • mode of production.

37
4. Historical Materialism
  • forces of production

38
4. Historical Materialism
  • relations of production

39
4. Historical Materialism
  • Mode of production

40
5. Analysis of the Capitalistic Method of
Production
  • 5.1. Simple Reproduction

41
5.2. Basics of the Extended Reproduction
42
5.3. Capitalistic Society and Justice
43
5.4. The Real Capitalistic Exploitation Process
the Production
44
6. Marx as Scientific Economist
  • The main merit of Marx is presumably what
    Schumpeter called (198026) the economic
    conception of history
  • The economy is not an isolated subarea of human
    living as Aristotle conceived his Oikos in which
    the economy has its limited space.
  • In stead the economy penetrates the whole life
    and stands in near connection with the mental and
    intellectual life, philosophy, science and all
    other parts of culture.

45
6. Marx as Scientific Economist
  • The economy forms our perception of the world
    much stronger than philosophy assumed it until
    that time.
  • However, this implies, that the economic
    conception of history of Marx is rather
  • sociological than a
  • scientifically economic perspective.
  • Marx is strongest whenever he is
  • on the ground of philosophy and
  • where he argues qualitatively in the economy.
  • .

46
6. Marx as Scientific Economist
  • Similar as the mythological figure Antaios, Marx
    is invincible as long as he is standing on the
    ground of philosophy.
  • But as Antaios,
  • he is losing his power
  • as soon as he leaves the ground of philosophy
  • and
  • does not anymore argue qualitatively
  • but economically quantitatively.

47
6. Marx as Scientific Economist
  • His quantifications are notoriously weak and the
    deficits
  • in the explaining of prices via the labor theory
    of values as well as
  • in the law of the fall of the rate of profit
  • are incurable.
  • It is not possible to extend
  • the Marxian economics to a theory which is
    comparable
  • to the theory of a general equilibrium of
    neoclassical economics.

48
6. Marx as Scientific Economist
  • Elster (1986) summarizes Marx achievement in the
    following way
  • It is
  • strongest in history and sociology and
  • weakest in economics and politics.

49
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
  • Marx orientates himself in on classical economics
    of Smith and Ricardo.
  • While Smith sees mainly the social and
    communicative dimensions, Marx is immediately
    fascinated of the object which is exchanged, the
    commodity.
  • While Smith sees immediately the coordination
    which the exchange effects, namely that goods are
    allocated and reach to where they are needed,
    Marx is not interested in the coordinative
    function of the market.

50
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the
Transformation Problem
  • As stated above in Section 3 Marx
  • Marx delivers a critique of political economy,
  • but at the same time he wants to give an
    explicative theory of the modern economy,
  • which together stands in the service of
    revolutionizing the world.

51
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the
Transformation Problem
  • We want to ask whether Marx developed in his
    monograph Capital an economic theory of the
    modern economy which is superior or at least
    equal to modern Nonmarxian economics?
  • Marx argues that modern economy is an exchange
    economy. The value of each commodity is equal to
    the human labor which is embodied in it. This is
    the nucleus of the labor theory of value.

52
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
  • Marx learned this approach from one of the great
    classical economists, David Riccardo (1772-1823).
  • In contrast to Ricardo, Marx applied this theory
    also to labor itself, insofar as the capability
    to create value.

53
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
  • The value of labor is equal to the labor value
    which is necessary for the reproduction of labor
    (i.e. all the goods which a labor needs to
    reproduce himself and his family, in particular
    his off springs).
  • But a worker produces more than its value is
    worth
  • A worker laboring 10 hours and producing a
    corresponding worth, can reproduce himself with
    goods for which only 6 hours labor are needed.
  • The difference between 10 6 4 is called
    surplus value.

54
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
  • Buying the manpower of a laborer and
  • using it for his purpose the entrepreneur
    acquires the surplus value in form of profits.
  • Result This argumentation explains the origin of
    profits.
  • The problem of this value analysis is that profit
    can only be realized
  • in an exchange economy
  • in which prices are paid.

55
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
  • The value is an inner quality of the commodity
  • The price is an externally recognizable
    information.
  • Marx has to assert that the value determines the
    price.
  • The transformation of values of commodities into
    market prices of the commodities is known as the
    transformation problem.
  • The transformation problem can only be solved
  • under very restrictive conditions
  • which in reality never hold.

56
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
  • These conditions are
  • Labor is the only scarce factor of production.
  • There is no joint production,
  • There is no technical progress.
  • The market structure is characterized by perfect
    competition.
  • In addition, the folllowing conditions have to
    hold
  • The growth of the population is constant
    (Weizsäcker und Samuelson 1971/1974).
  • The time preference and the distribution of
    income have has to fulfil restrictive conditions.
  • Nonrenewable and recnewable natural resources
    have to be not scarce.

57
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
  • Marx has attempted to solve the transformation
    problem in his third volume of Capital which was
    published by Friedrich Engels only after his
    death, or perhaps correctly said, to conceal it.
  • This endeavor has lead
  • to many ambiguities and
  • great confusion and
  • extremely complicated the understanding of his
    work.

58
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
  • Desai (2002 264) explains the problems of the
    labour theory of value in case of the
    circumstance that the production needs tiem
  • A classic example is winemaking. When grapes are
    harvested and crushed, labour is used. But then
    the grape juice is left to ferment for some time
    before we have wine. The value of the wine
    exceeds that of the grape juice by a large
    factor, yet labour contributes nothing to the
    extra value. Thus, value and surplus could arise
    from factors other than labour.

59
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
Conclusion Marx theoretical approach is not
suited to give a quantitative analysis of the
economy and a scientifically satisfying empirical
description of the economy. While the disparity
between value analysis and price theory and Marx
attempts to cover the tension between the two of
them, the lecture of his texts vary cumbersome
matters get even more complicated by an actually
ambiguity of Marx concept of value or as Petry
(1916 28) said by the Janus face of the Marxian
theory of value.
60
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
The main deficit of the labour theory of value is
that the scarcity problem and thus the demand
side is not taken care of. Roemer (1988 49)
The labor theory of value is a supply-side
theory The correct theory of market price
must take both supply and demand into
account. During the last decades, most Marxian
economists have agreed to the conclusion, that
the labour theory of value can neither be a
theoretical nor a empirical the basis of the
explanation of market prices (Brody 1970,
Morishima 1973,Cohen 1978, Roemer 1981, Elster
1985). In particular it can be shown that it is
possible to study problems as for example the
exploitation and the conflict of classes
successfully without employing the labour theory
of value.
61
6.1 Labour Theory of Value and the Transformation
Problem
  • Can we definitely say that labour theory of value
    is disproved?
  • Strict proofs do not exist concerning questions
    like this one.
  • We also cannot exclude the possibility that the
    labour theory of value might once be employed for
    relevantly quantitative analysis, even if we
    consider this to be highly improbable.

62
6.2. The Law of the Falling Rate of Profit
  • One of the central integral parts of Marxian
    Economics is the law of the falling rate of
    profit.
  • Marx considered it to be the most essential law
    of motion of the capitalistic system.
  • It says
  • The profit per unit of employed capital is
    falling in the long run.
  • Marx only systemized an insight of classical
    economists like Ricardo (1772-1823) and Malthus
    (1768-1834).
  • While the latter assumed that land became more
    scarce, Marx saw the increasing amount of capital
    as the main cause.

63
6.2. The Law of the Falling Rate of Profit
  • Marx differentiate between variable capital v
    (labour) ND constant capital k (machines, tools,
    houses, shades, ships etc.).
  • Marx assumes that the constant capital always
    grows faster than the variable capital. From this
    follows , i.e. that the organic composition of
    capital which is the relation between constant
    capital c and total capital v c always grows
    (Sweezy 1942 chapter 6).
  • Marx concludes that the rate of profit has to
    fall, because he considers the variable capital
    as the only source of profit.
  • Technical progress can increase the rate of
    surplus, but not the tendency of fall compensate.

64
6.2. The Law of the Falling Rate of Profit
  • The Law of the Falling Rate of Profit was
    controversially debated for a long time, but
    during the second half of the 20th century there
    developed a consensus between Marxist and
    Neoclassical economists that this law is not
    valid.
  • (Sweezy 194 Chapter 6, Okishio 1961, Samuelson
    1972, Morishima 1973, Roemer 1981 Chapters 4 und
    5, Elster, 1986 192-193)
  • A proof for this consensus is given on the next
    slide.
  • For a critical assessment of those authors who
    are of different opinion see Roemer 1981 117-8,
    123-4.

65
6.2. The Law of the Falling Rate of Profit
  • Let e be the rate of exploitation or rate of
    surplus value,
  • which is defined by the relation of surplus
    value to variable capital and
  • let v be the variable and k the constant capital.
  • Then the rate of profit p is defined by p e
    v/(vk).
  • Let the variable capital be the numeraire, i.e.
    the value of one unit of labour is equal to 1,
  • then we can express the value of the constant
    capital in units of the variable capital, Hence,
    the rate of proftio p simplifies to p e/(1k).
  • We see imediately that there does not exist a
    nonambigious tendency for p, bedause the rate of
    exploitation e does not need to increase as much
    as the constant capital, in oder to keep the rate
    of profit p constant (see Roemer 1981 117-8 and
    123-4).

66
6.2. The Law of the Falling Rate of Profit
  • Marx had assumed that the steady fall of the rate
    of profit would lead to complete collapse of the
    capitalistic system.
  • This expectations has yet not confirmed.

67
6.3. Joint Production and its Repercussions on
the Environment
Marx was the only classical economist who dealt
extensively with the environmental and resource
problem (Kurz 1986, Baumgärtner 1999 104-107).
He even conceived them as problems of joint
production. What does this mean? To give an
example
68
6.3. Joint Production and its Repercussions on
the Environment
  • Example of Joint Production
  • A two-person household needs yearly
  • 4000 kwh electrical energy to produce this
  • amount with lignite (brown coal).
  • 6000 l water steam,
  • 21600 m3 air emissions,
  • 3200 l waste water,
  • 288 kg ashes are generated as by-products

69
6.3. Joint Production and its Repercussions on
the Environment
  • He even discussed recycling of waste and to
    regain resources from recycling processes.
    (Baumgärtner, Faber, Schiller 2006, 114-116)
  • However, he thought that all environmental and
    resource problems would finally be solved because
    of human creativity to transform all waste
    products into valuable goods.
  • It is noteworthy that Marx perspective was
    singular and unique at his time. His awareness of
    this issue demonstrates Marx extraordinary
    ability to analyze the dynamics of the
    capitalistic system. But Marx didnt integrate
    his view into his economic theory and downplayed
    it.

70
6.3. Joint Production and its Repercussions on
the Environment
  • As proved by Baumgärtner, Faber, Schiller (2006,
    Chapter 3) Marx view is not valid
  • From a thermodynamic point of view, every
    production yields joint products.
  • Every industrial production is characterized by
    joint products in form of waste and emissions.

71
Typical Industrial Production ProcessExample
Iron Manufacturing
Thermodynamics ? every industrial production
is joint production
72
6.3. Joint Production and its Repercussions on
the Environment
  • One may as well ask why Marx believed so much in
    progress. This may as well be a consequence of
    the great admiration he had for the capitalistic
    bourgeoisie, which is documented in his Communist
    Manifesto (jointly published with Friedrich
    Engels in 1848 62)
  • It (the bourgeoisie, M.F.) has been the first to
    show what man's activity can bring about. It has
    accomplished wonders far surpassing Egyptian
    pyramids, Roman aqueducts, and Gothic cathedrals
    it has conducted expeditions that put in the
    shade all former exoduses of nations and
    crusades.

73
6.3. Joint Production and its Repercussions on
the Environment
  • The bourgeoisie, during its rule of scarce one
    hundred years, has created more massive and more
    colossal productive forces than have all
    preceding generations together.
  • (Marx and Engels 1848 63)

74
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems
  • Why did Marx understand so well the dynamics of
    the capitalistic system?
  • Marx had the ability to see unintended
    consequences of our actions.
  • Two areas in which these unintended organize
    themselves and become to a determining factor.
    These areas are
  •  
  • the economy and
  • nature

75
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems

Marxs View on the Economy Marx recognized that
the production of wealth always goes hand in hand
with the creation of poorness and that this
happens although the actors do not intend this
production of pauperism. The poorness does not
arise by the fact that people rob so others, but
poorness is an unavoidable consequence of the
capitalistic system and its dynamics. This was
already observed by the philosopher F.W. Hegel
(1821/1970) in his Philosophy of Right. But Marx
analyzed this connectivity more in detail than
Hegel, for he developed this idea to a precision
tool for the study of social change (Elster
1986 38-39).
76
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems

Marxs View on the Environment But on the other
side this Marxian analytical instrument may also
be fruitfully employed to study the unintended
consequences of the repercussions of the
capitalistic market system on nature. Marx dealt
extensively with environmental and resource
problems.
77
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems
  • Capitalism had survived not only survived, but
    become a dynamic worldwide phenomenon yet again,
    the first time since 1914. It showed a capacity
    for technological advance with promises of more
    to come. Across the world people abandoned
    socialism as a cure for their problems. Warts and
    all, it was capitalism they wanted. Capitalism
    had still a lot of potential it was not yet
    ready to lie down and die.

78
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems
  • Desai was inspired to his diagnosis by a central
    thesis of Marx (1959/0421)
  • No social order ever disappears before all the
    productive forces for which there is room in it
    have been developed and the new higher relations
    of production never appear before the material
    conditions of their existence have matured in the
    womb of the old society itself. Therefore,
    mankind always sets itself only such tasks as it
    can solve since looking at the matter more
    closely, we will always find that the task itself
    arises only when the material conditions
    necessary for the solution already exist, or are
    at least in the process of formation

79
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems
  • Desai is correct in taking the development of
    the world after 1989 as an indication that Marx
    assertion concerning the dynamics of the method
    of production is appropriate If this is true,
    then the capitalism would have a splendid future
    still to come
  • it has not yet reached its limits in the
    developed countries and
  • more and more countries and economies are
    globally captured by capitalism.
  • However in the past, this dynamic has been linked
    with
  • an ever growing demand of environmental services
    and
  • resource capacities.

80
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems
  • Empirical evidence for this hypothesis is the
  • increase of consumption of energy and
  • the corresponding increase of CO2.
  • Since the environmental conference in Rio in 1992
    both quantities grew
  • by 40 percent and
  • this tendency is still unbowed until the recent
    present.

81
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems
  • Consequence
  • perspective for the future safeguard of the
    natural environmental conditions looks somber
    the reasons are
  • at least 3 billions human beings of the world
    population have a backlog demand to satisfy
    basic need, such as food, clothing, housing,
    clean water, health services and education. Even
    in China many of its inhabitants are in need of
    these goods and services
  • in addition, we have to recognize that the world
    population will grow by another 3 billions people
    until 2050.

82
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems
  • Consequences
  • words it does not seem possible
  •  to conserve globally the intake capacity of the
    environment for pollutants and
  • to make available sufficient amounts of resources
    for the production and consumption of 9 billions
    people
  • The resulting damages of nature and the shortages
    of natural resources would be disastrous not only
    to nature, but would also be a permanent source
    of conflicts.
  •  
  •  

83
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the Thereby Effected Environmental
and Resource Problems
  • Policy recommendation
  • Decoupling of economic growth and
  • the use of exhaustible and nonrenewable resources
    as well as
  • the depletion of the environmental capacity of
    disposing and cleaning up waste.

84
6.4. The Dynamics of the Capitalistic System
and the thereby effected Environmental
and Resource Problems
  • If
  • the decoupling of economic growth and
  • the environmental strain
  • cannot be achieved then it may well be that Karl
    Marx is right with his prediction that
  • the capitalistic system will collapse,
  • although in quite a different manner was as he
    had thought (see also Desai 2002 9f).

85
6.5 Marx and Socialism
  • It is not quite clear, what Marxs contribution
    to socialism and communism has been.
  • Friedrich Engels maintained that Marx brought
    socialism from utopia to science.
  • Thus he insinuated that Marx had develop a theory
    of socialism. Such a theory had to deliver
    insights into the economic structure of
    socialism.

86
6.5 Marx and Socialism
  • Engels suggestion led
  • many to attempt to develop such an economic
    theory of socialism.
  • Further, the Soviet Union and other socialist
    countries had attempted to develop a socialism
    according to the principles of Marx until 1989.
  • After 1989 many thought that the failure of the
    socialistic experiment disproved a theory of
    socialism, too.
  • Not few even thought that not only Marx analysis
    was in totally confuted, but also that he was
    responsible for the failure of the socialistic
    experiment.

87
6.5 Marx and Socialism
  • However, it is emphasized in the scientific
    debate on socialism that the failure of the
    soviet socialistic experiment does not imply that
    another experiment might not be successful (see
    e.g. Roemer 1994).
  • It is expedient to recognize that there does not
    exist a theoretical framework which is comparable
    with the neoclassical framework, warts and all of
    it given.
  • Desai (2002.3-4) noted that Marx did not attempt
    to supply such a theory, for he considered
    himself not as a theorist of socialism, but as a
    critique of capitalism.

88
6.6 Concluding Remarks
  • Sometimes Marx is called the last classical
    economist. But this connotation does not seem
    justified.
  • Das wird Marx jedoch nicht ganz gerecht, da er
    eine neue Richtung ökonomischer Forschung
    geschaffen hat die marxistische Ökonomie. Diese
    hat sich sowohl in Auseinandersetzung mit der
    herrschenden Wirtschaftswissenschaft als auch
    eigenständig entwickelt. Darüber hinaus gilt Marx
    als Begründer des Zwei-Faktoren-Zwei-Sektoren
    Wachstumsmodelles und damit der Wachstumstheorie
    (Krelle 1979 460-1) sowie mit seinen
    Ausführungen im 2. Band des Kapitals (MEW 24
    391-518) als Vorläufer der von Wassily Leontief
    (1905-1999) entwickelten Input-Output-Analyse
    (Leontief 1951). Beide sind im Laufe des 20.
    Jahrhunderts zu wichtigen Bereichen der
    herkömmlichen Wirtschaftswissenschaften geworden.
    Auch haben seine Ideen einen der wichtigsten
    Ökonomen des 20. Jahrhunderts, Joseph Schumpeter,
    in dessen Theorie der wirtschaftlichen
    Entwicklung beeinflusst, die wiederum zur
    Entstehung eines neuen Zweiges der
    Wirtschaftswissenschaften im letzten Viertel des
    20. Jahrhunderts, der Evolutorischen Ökonomie,
    geführt hat. Marx Beitrag zur Umwelt- und
    Rohstoffökonomik haben wir bereits oben
    gewürdigt. Marx hat viele neue Fragen gestellt.
    Dieses Verdienst wird auch nicht dadurch
    geschmälert, dass er oft keine zufriedenstellenden
    , sondern nur unzureichende oder sogar falsche
    Antworten auf diese Fragen gegeben hat. Man kann
    daher durchaus sagen, wenige Ökonomen haben so
    nachhaltig die Wirtschaftswissenschaften
    beeinflusst, wie das Karl Marx getan hat.
  • Vgl. Desai (2002 56f) und Samuelson (1971 242).
    Einschränkend meint Elster (1986 10) the
    schemes of simple and extended reproduction,
    which anticipate modern input-output analysis,
    although the gist of Marx analysis can be stated
    in one page whereas he uses more than hundred.
  • Siehe Haustein (1998) und Weise (1998), die aus
    zwei unterschiedlichen Perspektiven den Einfluss
    von Marx auf die Evolutorische Ökonomie zeigen.

89
7. Labour Theory of Value, Theory of the State
and Income Distribution7.1. Theory of the
State
  • Marx considered himself as a political economist,
    but did he dispose over a theory of the state?
    Desai (2002 8) has no doubt concerning the lack
    of such a theory. (But) now his lack of a theory
    of the state, of classes, of agency in political
    were all pointed out.
  • Marx, certainly has never developed
    systematically a theory of the state there
    exist, however, hints in his work (Elster 1986
    2, 143).
  • Thus Elster speaks of an abdication theory
    which states that capitalists abstain from
    political power because they find their interests
    better served this way. Elster argues that if
    certain alterations are taken care of then the
    Marxian conception of the state is that that the
    state is an independent actor in the social
    arena, of which Marx assumes that the interests
    of the capitalist class serve as constraints
    rather than goals for its actions.

90
7.2. Income Distribution
91
8. Summary
92
(No Transcript)
93
Literature
  • Die Schriften von Karl Marx und Friedrich Engels
    werden in der Regel nach der Ausgabe der Marx
    Engels Werke, Berlin (MEW), zitiert.
  •  Aristoteles (1994) Politik. Reinbek Rowohlt.
  • Aristoteles (1995) Die Nikomachische Ethik. Nach
    der Übersetzung von Eugen Rolfes bearbeitet von
    Günther Bien, Hamburg.
  • Baumgärtner, Stefan (2000) Ambivalent Joint
    Production and the Natural Environment.
    Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg, New York.
  • Baumgärtner, Stefan, Malte Faber und Johannes
    Schiller (2006) Joint Production and
    Responsibilty in Ecological Economics. On the
    Foundation of Environmental Policy, Edward Elgar,
    Cheltenham UK, Northampton, MA, USA.
  • Berlin, Isaiah (1963/1971) Karl Marx, Piper
    Co., München, 1963, zitiert aus H. Claus
    Recktenwald (Hrsg.), Karl Marx, Geschichte der
    Politischen Ökonomie, Kröner, Stuttgart 300-322.
  • Bernholz, Peter und Malte Faber (1971) Diskussion
    einiger Probleme der Arbeitswertlehre, Schmollers
    Jahrbuch 91 657-668.
  • Bernholz, Peter und Malte Faber (1972)
    Diskussion einiger Probleme der Arbeitswertlehre
    bei erweiterter Reproduktion Zeitschrift für
    Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften 92
    389-305.

94
Literature
  • Böhm-Bawerk, von Eugen. (1896) Zum Abschluß des
    Marxschen Systems, in O. Häring (Hrsg.)
    Staatswissenschaftliche Arbeiten. Festgaben für
    Karl Knies, Berlin. (nach dem Text des
    Wiederabdruckes in Hans G. Nutzinger und Elmar
    Wolfstetter 1974a 97-127).
  • Brody, Andrew (1970) Proportion, Prices and
    Planning, New York, American Elsevier.
  • Cohen, Gerald A. (1978) Karl Marxs Theory of
    History, Princeton University Press, Princeton.
  • Elster, Jon (1986) An Introduction to Karl Marx,
    Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
  • Engels, Friedrich (1844) Umrisse zu einer Kritik
    der Nationalökonomie. (MEW 1, 499-524).
  • Fetscher, Iring. (Hrsg.) (1966) Marx-Engels
    Studienausgabe, Bände I bis IV, Fischer Bücherei,
    Frankfurt a.M.
  • Gehlen, Arnold (2004) Urmensch und Spätkultur.
    Philosophische Ergebnisse und Aussagen.
    Klostermann, Frankfurt/Main.
  • Haustein, Heinz-Dieter (1998) Karl Marx und
    evolutorische Ökonomik in Warnke und Huber
    (Hrsg.) (1998) 151-178.

95
Literature
  • Hegel, Georg Wilhelm Friedrich (1969)
    Wissenschaft der Logik. Teil II. Frankfurt am
    Main.
  • Hegel, Georg Wilhelm Friedrich (1970) Grundlinien
    der Philosophie des Rechts oder Naturrecht und
    Staatswissenschaft im Grundrisse (1821).
    Frankfurt am Main.
  • Hegel, Georg Wilhelm Friedrich (1970a)
    Vorlesungen über die Philosophie der Geschichte.
    Frankfurt am Main.
  • Hegel, Georg Wilhelm Friedrich (1983) Vorlesungen
    über Naturrecht und Staatswissenschaft.
    Heidelberg 1817/18 mit Nachträgen aus der
    Vorlesung 1818/19. Nachgeschrieben von P.
    Wannenmann.
  • Kurz, Heinz-Dieter (1986) "Neoclassical
    economists on joint production, Metroeconomica,
    38 1-37.
  • Lange, Oskar (1936/1956) On the economic theory
    of socialism, in B. Lippincott (Hrsg.), Market
    Socialism, University of Minnesota Press,
    Minneapolis.
  • Leontief, Wassily (1951) The Structure of the
    American Economy, New York.
  • Locke, John (1983) Über die Regierung. Stuttgart
    Reclam 1983.
  • Löwith, Karl (1979) Weltgeschichte und
    Heilsgeschehen, Kohlhammer, Berlin, Mainz, Köln.

96
Literature
  • Löwith, Karl (1990) Marxismus und Geschichte,
    in K. Löwith, Der Mensch inmitten der Geschichte,
    J.B. Metzlersche Verlagsbuchhandlung, Stuttgart
    207-222.
  • Marx, Karl (1844) Zur Kritik der Hegelschen
    Rechtsphilosophie, Einleitung. (MEW 1, 378-391)
  • Marx, Karl (1894) Das Kapital. Dritter Band. Buch
    III Der Gesamtprozeß der kapitalistischen
    Produktion. Marx Engels Werke, Band 25. Berlin.
  • Marx, Karl (1875) Kritik des Gothaer Programms
    (Randglossen zum Programm der Deutschen
    Arbeiterpartei). In Marx Engels Werke, Band 19.
    Berlin, 11-32.
  • Marx, Karl (1879/80) Randglossen zu A. Wagners
    Lehrbuch der politischen Ökonomie. In Marx
    Engels Werke, Band 19. Berlin, 355-383.
  • Marx, Karl (1844) Zur Judenfrage. (MEW 1,
    347-377).
  • Marx, Karl (1859) Zur Kritik der Politischen
    Ökonomie. (MEW 13, 5-160).
  • Marx, Karl (1859) Einleitung zur Kritik der
    Politischen Ökonomie. (MEW 13, 615-641).
  • Marx, Karl (1867 Das Kapital. Erster Band. Buch
    I Der Produktionsprozeß des Kapitals. Marx
    Engels Werke, Band 23. Berlin.
  • Marx, Karl (1885) Das Kapital. Zweiter Band. Buch
    II Der Zirkulationsprozeß des Kapitals.
  • .

97
Literature
  • Marx Engels Werke, Band 24. Berlin.
  • Marx, Kar und Friedrich Engels (1846) Deutsche
    Ideologie (MEW Bd. 3).
  • Marx, Karl und Friedrich Engels (1848) Manifest
    der Kommunistischen Partei. In Marx Engels
    Werke, Band 4. Berlin, 459-493.
  • MacIntyre, Alasdair (1984) After Virtue. A Study
    in Moral Theory. Second Edition. Notre Dame,
    Indiana 1984.
  • Meek, Ronald L. (1967) Die ökonomische Methode
    von Karl Marx in Hans G. Nutzinger und Elmar
    Wolfstetter 1974b 12-38. Übersetzt aus dem
    Englischen Karl Marxs Economic Method in R.
    L. Meek 1967, Economics and Ideology and Other
    Essays, Chapman Hall, London 93-112.
  • Morishima. Michio (1973) Marxs Economics.
    Cambridge Cambridge University Press.
  • Müller-Fürstenberger, Georg (1995)
    Kuppelproduktion. Eine theoretische und
    empirische Analyse am Beispiel der chemischen
    Industrie, Heidelberg, New York, Physica.
  • Nutzinger, Hans G. und Elmar Wolfstetter (Hrsg.)
    (1974a) Die Marxsche Theorie und ihre Kritik I.
    eine Textsammlung zur Kritik der Politischen
    Ökonomie, Herder Herder, Frankfurt a. M., New
    York.

98
Literature
  • Nutzinger, Hans G. und Elmar Wolfstetter (Hrsg.)
    (1974b) Die Marxsche Theorie und ihre Kritik II.
    eine Textsammlung zur Kritik der Politischen
    Ökonomie, Herder Herder, Frankfurt a. M., New
    York.
  • Okishio, Nobuo (1961) Technische Veränderungen
    und Profitrate, in in Hans G. Nutzinger und
    Elmar Wolfstetter 1974b 1732-191. Übersetzt aus
    dem Englischen Technical changes and the rate of
    profit, Kobe University 7, 1961 85-90.
  • Petersen, Thomas und Fulda, Haans Friedrich
    (1999) Hegels System der Bedürfnisse. In
    DIALEKTIK 3/99, 129-146.
  • Petry, Franz (1916) Der soziale Gehalt der
    Arbeitswertlehre, G. Fischer, Jena.
  • Priddat, Birger P. (1990) Hegel als Ökonom.
    Berlin 1990.
  • Rawls, John (1975) Eine Theorie der
    Gerechtigkeit. Frankfurt am Main.
  • Roemer, John E. (1981) Analytical Foundations of
    Marxian Economic Theory, Cambridge University
    Press, Cambridge, UK, USA.
  • Roemer, John E. (1988) Free to Lose. An
    Introduction to Marxist Economic Philosophy,
    Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass., USA.
  • Roemer, John E. (1994) A Future for Socialism,
    Havard University Press, Cambridge, Mass.

99
Literature
  • Samuelsson, Paul A. (1971) Understanding the
    Marxian notion of exploitation a summary of the
    so-called transformation problem between values
    and competitive Prices, Journal of Economic
    Literature 9 399-431. (Deutsche Übersetzung in
    Hans G. Nutzinger und Elmar Wolfstetter
    1974b237-295) .
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1964) Theorie der
    wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Eine Untersuchung
    über Unternehmergewinn, Kapital, Kredit, Zins und
    den Konjunkturzyklus. Sechste Auflage. Berlin.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1980) Kapitalismus,
    Sozialismus und Demokratie. Fünfte Auflage.
    München 1980 (übersetzt aus dem Amerikanischen
    Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York
    1942).
  • Smith, Adam (1775/1978) Der Wohlstand der
    Nationen. Übersetzt von Claus Recktenwald.
    München.
  • Smolinski, Leon (1973) Karl Marx and
    mathematical economics, Journal of PoliticaL
    Economics 81 1189-1204.
  • Sweezy, Paul. M. (1970) Theorie der
    kapitalistischen Entwicklung, Suhrkamp, Frankfurt
    a.M. (übersetzt aus dem Amerikanischen The Theory
    of Capitalist Development Principles of Marxist
    Political Economy, Monthly Review 1942).
  • Warnke, Camilla und Gerhard Huber (Hrsg.) (1998)
    Die ökonomische Theorie von Marx was bleibt?
    Metropolis, Marburg.

100
Literature
  • Weise, Peter (1998) Evolution und
    Selbstorganisation bei Karl Marx, in Camilla
    Warnke und Gerhard Huber (Hrsg.) (1998)179-192.
  • Weizsäcker, von Carl Christian und Paul A.
    Samuelson (1971/1974) Eine neue Arbeitswertlehre
    als Planungsinstrument unter Verwendung der
    bürgerlichen Profitrate. In Hans G. Nutzinger
    und Elmar Wolfstätter (1974 54-61). Übersetzt
    aus dem Englischen A new Labor Theory of Value
    for Rational Planning through Use of the
    Bourgeois Profit Rate. In Proceedings of the
    National Academy of Sciences, USA, Vol. No. 6
    1192-1194, 1971.
  • Wolfstetter, Elmar (1979) Marxistische
    Werttheorie, in Reinhard Selten (Hrsg.)
    Handwörterbuch der Mathematischen
    Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Band 1
    Wirtschaftstheorie, Gabler, Wiesbaden 205-212.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com