12. Market Entry and the Emergence of Perfect Competition - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 27
About This Presentation
Title:

12. Market Entry and the Emergence of Perfect Competition

Description:

monopolist's profits will attract entrants, which diminishes the former monopolist's profits. ... 12.4 Entry Prevention, Overinvestment, and the Dixit-Spence Model ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:94
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 28
Provided by: EngE91
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: 12. Market Entry and the Emergence of Perfect Competition


1
12. Market Entry and the Emergence of Perfect
Competition
  • 12.1 The Need for Entry-Prevention Strategies
  • monopolists profits will attract entrants, which
    diminishes the former monopolists profits. Hence
    he would like to prevent entry
  • 12.2 Limit Pricing in the Bain, Modigliani,
    Sylos-Labini Model
  • basic idea incumbent chooses a quantity high
    enough such that remaining demand is too low for
    entry to pay
  • term limit pricing might appear a bit
    inconsistent since the strategic variable is
    quantity

2
  • assumptions
  • two periods pre-entry (t0) and entry (t1). In
    period 1 entrant decides whether to enter
  • one established firm, incumbent, i, and one
    potential entrant, e
  • consumers are not loyal, no switching costs
  • demand does not change over time
  • in period 0, i will commit to output level xi,
    which it will maintain in future periods
  • e believes that if e enters i will maintain xi
    independent of es actions and market price
  • last 2 assumptions are critical and problematic

3
  • Blockading Market Entry
  • assume linear inverse demand p a - b(qiqe)
  • in period 0 qe 0, so i faces p a bqi
  • profit maximum attains for qi qm (Fig 12.1)
  • e faces residual demand p (a bqm) bqe,
    demand is shifted down (Fig 12.2)
  • if residual demand is so low (always below
    average cost) that e cannot recover costs for any
    output, e will not enter
  • entry is blockaded, i can prevent entry by simply
    producing monopoly quantity (and hence obtains
    the best possible outcome)
  • depends of course on assumptions 5 and (in
    particular) 6

4
  • Impeding Market Entry
  • if the residual demand after i chooses qm is
    sufficient for e to make a profit (Fig 12.4),
    blockading entry by producing monopoly quantity
    is not possible
  • but i can impede entry by producing a quantity
    qLgtqm that shifts residual demand further down
    such that it is tangent to es average cost curve
    and hence e cannot make profit (Fig 12.5)
  • hence e will not enter
  • qL is called limit quantity and the associated pL
    limit price
  • qL is the smallest quantity and pL the highest
    price that impede entry

5
  • 12.3 Criticisms of the Bain, Modigliani,
    Sylos-Labini Model Subgame Perfection
  • game first stage (period 0) i chooses quantity,
    second stage (period 1) e decides whether to
    enter if e enters, third stage (period 1) i
    decides whether to stick to quantity from period
    0 (Fig 12.6)
  • assumptions 5 and 6 say i threatens to stick to
    qL chosen in period 0 also in period 1
  • but threat is not credible
  • assume entrant will choose Cournot-equilibrium
    quantity if he enters
  • by backward induction the only subgame-perfect
    equilibrium is qm in period 0, e enters, and
    then i changes quantity to Cournot-equilibrium
    quantity
  • given that entry occurs, i should adapt level to
    best reply, hence it pays to enter, i maximizes
    in period 0
  • how can incumbent commit to a quantity that
    deters entry?

6
  • 12.4 Entry Prevention, Overinvestment, and the
    Dixit-Spence Model
  • Consulting Report 12.2 overinvestiment in
    capacity makes threat of producing large quantity
    credible and entry deterrence subgame-perfect
    strategy
  • model if firm has installed production capacity
    K, then marginal cost for quantity ltK is v, but
    for quantity gtK, marginal cost is vs.
  • If a firm has excess capacity, i.e. more capital
    than needed, than for additional unit only
    additional variable inputs are needed, but if
    there is no excess capacity, then for each unit
    the capacity has to be extended (Fig 12.8)
  • incumbent has capacity K, hence cost function is
  • Ci(q,K)vqF for qltK, Ci(q,K)vqs(q-K)F for q ?
    K
  • the entrant has not build capacity, hence cost
    function is
  • Ce(q,K)(vs)qF, will enter only if fixed costs
    F can be covered

7
  • due to fixed costs, reaction curve of e drops to
    0 at an output level of i that drives down prices
    far enough, call this quantity qL limit quantity
    (Fig 12.9)
  • the reaction function of the incumbent depends on
    its capacity
  • lower marginal cost implies a higher best
    response (because best response is quantity where
    MRMC)
  • hence is reaction function Ri(0) for marginal
    cost vs (K0) is below Ri(Q(0)) for marginal
    cost v (K is large enough to satisfy whole demand
    at price 0)
  • for intermediate capacity K, the reaction
    function Ri(K) is equal to Ri(Q(0)) for qltK and
    then drops down to Ri(0)
  • game period 0 i chooses K, period 1 e decides
    whether to enter, period 2 quantities are chosen
    (simultaneously)
  • if K0, outcome will be Cournot-equilibrium.
  • But if K ?qL (and v is small enough), es best
    response would be to produce nothing and hence
    not to enter
  • subgame perfect, because i chooses optimally
    after entry
  • i builds capacity higher than monopoly quantity
    for MC vs

8
  • 12.5 Perfect Competition as the Limit of
    Successful Entry When Entry Prevention Fails
  • assume incumbent cannot prevent entry and there
    are eventually n firms
  • output of firm 1 q1, etc, total output is Q
    q1... qn
  • inverse demand p(Q)
  • in case of monopoly the price is p MC/1-
    1/?(Q)
  • now for firm i the marginal revenue is
    MRip(Q)(dp/dQ)qi
  • rewrite MRip(Q) 1 (dp/dQ) (Q/p(Q)) (qi/Q)
  • denote by qi/Q si firm is market share, then
  • MRip(Q) 1- si / ?(Q)
  • a profit maximizing oligopolist will choose qi
    such that MRiMCi, and hence p(Q) MCi / 1- si
    / ?(Q)
  • thus the price markup will be smaller than in
    monopoly and is decreasing in si and hence in
    the number of firms price converges to marginal
    cost as number of firms goes to ?

9
  • The Characteristics of Perfectly Competitive
    Markets
  • as number of firm grows, price converges to
    marginal costs and hence to the
    welfare-maximizing outcome
  • for a large number of firms, the demand a firm
    faces is essentially flat (infinitely elastic)
    it cannot influence the price and only decide how
    much to produce at a given price
  • firms act as price takers, industry of
    price-taking firms constitutes a perfectly
    competitive market,
  • characteristics of perfectly competitive markets
  • many firms with insubstantial market shares
  • free entry, no barriers to entry
  • homogenous product, i.e. all firms produce the
    same
  • perfect factor mobility, can move to and from
    other industries
  • perfect information, all participants know price
    and potential profits

10
  • Appendix Incomplete Information and Entry
    Prevention
  • Milgrom-Roberts Model there are two possible
    technologies and hence two different possible
    marginal costs
  • game period 0 nature determines the level of
    marginal cost for incumbent, only i is informed
    about his marginal cost
  • period 1 incumbent acts as monopolist, selects
    quantity and earns profit
  • period 2 entrant decides whether to enter (has
    fixed cost K) if yes, e learns is marginal
    costs they play Cournot-game
  • assume e would not like to enter if i has low
    cost, but would like to enter if i has high cost
  • then high cost incumbent would like to pretend to
    have low cost

11
  • if es expected payoff against probability
    distribution of high and low is negative, there
    is pooling equilibrium both types of i produce
    low cost monopoly quantity, e does not enter
  • if es expected payoff against probability
    distribution of high and low is positive, there
    is separating equilibrium low cost type produces
    high quantity (this may be larger than the low
    cost monopoly quantity) such that high cost type
    is better off with high cost monopoly and then
    entry, e enters if i chooses low quantity (i.e.
    monopoly quantity of the high cost incumbent) in
    period 1

12
13. Perfectly Competitive Markets
  • If a monopolist cannot prevent market entry,
    firms will enter as long as this pays
  • if entry pays for many firms, this will
    eventually lead to a perfectly competitive
    market, with a large number of firms, free entry,
    a homogeneous product, factor mobility and
    complete information
  • 13.1 Competitive Markets in the Short Run
  • Quantity Decision of a Competitive Firm in the
    Short Run
  • In the short run, there is no further entry and
    firms have at least one fixed factor, call this
    capital, hence average total cost differs from
    average variable cost (in long run all costs are
    variable) (Fig 13.1)
  • in perfectly competitive market a firm has no
    influence on the price, so MRp and hence the
    firm will choose a quantity such that pMC if
    p?AVC, and q0 if pltAVC
  • the price need not cover the ATC because fixed
    cost are sunk

13
  • Supply Function of a Competitive Firm in the
    Short Run
  • supply function specifies how much a firm would
    be willing to sell at each possible price
  • this quantity is the one where pMC unless pltAVC,
    hence unless MCltAVC, i.e. unless q is smaller
    than the quantity q0 where AVC is minimal or p is
    smaller than p0MC(q0)
  • thus supply curve coincides with MC curve above
    (p0,q0) and is 0 below p0 (Fig 13.2)
  • The Market Supply Curve
  • like market demand curve, market supply curve or
    aggregate supply curve is obtained by
    horizontally adding the individual firms supply
    curves the result is the aggregate short-run
    marginal cost of supplying each unit (Fig 13.3)

14
  • Price Determination and the Definition of a
    Short-Run Equilibrium in a Competitive Market
  • a short-run equilibrium for a competitive market
    is price-quantity combination such that
  • no firm wishes to change the quantity it supplies
  • no consumer wishes to change the quantity he
    demands
  • the aggregate supply equals the aggregate demand
  • this means there is no force to change price or
    quantity
  • equilibrium is at the intersection of supply and
    demand
  • otherwise firms would offer lower prices (if SgtD)
    or consumers higher prices (if DgtS) (Fig 13.4)
  • In short-run equilibrium firms can make positive
    profits, which may differ according to their
    individual cost structure (Fig 13.5)

15
  • Policy Analysis in the Short Run Comparative
    Static Analysis
  • Policy changes can be evaluated by comparative
    static analysis, i.e. comparing the static
    equilibria before and after the change (e.g. in
    terms of consumer surplus)
  • in a dynamic analysis the path how the market
    moves from old to new equilibrium is examined
  • Example 13.1 Market for Illegal Drugs
  • increasing prosecution of trade of illegal drugs
    increases costs for dealers and users
  • targeting the dealers will shift up the supply
    curve, leading to a smaller quantity and a higher
    price
  • targeting the users will shift down the demand
    curve, leading to a smaller quantity and a lower
    price
  • the most effective strategy depends on which side
    is more sensitive to punishments (Fig 13.7)

16
  • Example 13.2 the Incidence of a Tax
  • who is actually paying a tax, i.e. if a tax is
    levied on producers, will this simply lead to an
    increase in prices?
  • the incidence of a tax, i.e. the ultimate
    distribution of the burden depends on the
    elasticity of demand (and supply)
  • if demand is perfectly inelastic, the consumers
    carry the whole burden, if it is perfectly
    inelastic, the producers do, for intermediate
    levels both share the burden, with the share of
    the producers increasing in the elasticity of the
    demand (Fig 13.8)
  • Tax Liability Side Equivalence it does not
    matter which side of the market a tax is levied
    on, i.e. for the economic incidence of the tax,
    the statutory (legal) incidence is irrelevant
  • Experimental Evidence Borck et al. (SEJ, 2002)
    in posted-offer markets tax liability side
    equivalence is confirmed net prices do not
    differ between treatments where either buyers or
    sellers pay the tax

17
Figure 2 Summary of experimental results (?
SellerTax, ? BuyerTax)
18
  • Example 13.3 Minimum Wage
  • installing a minimum wage above the equilibrium
    wage will lead to lower employment but a higher
    wage for those employed (Fig 13.9)
  • since unemployment might increase susceptibility
    for crime, abolishing minimum wage might appear
    an effective crime prevention strategy
  • but low wages (as in equilibrium) may make crime
    appear an alternative option as well
  • hence more effective might be to subsidize wages
    for low-skill workers, this leads to both higher
    wages and more employment (Fig 13.10)
  • disadvantages can be quite costly and leads to
    inefficiencies the marginal workers are paid
    more than their marginal product

19
  • 13.3 Competitive Markets in the Long Run
  • The Long-Run Equilibrium for Identical Firms
  • in a short-run equilibrium, firms can make
    extra-normal profits
  • but this situation cannot continue in the long
    run as long as firms make extra-normal profits,
    this will attract entry
  • long-run equilibrium is a price-quantity
    combination such that
  • no firm wishes to change the amount it supplies
  • no consumer wishes to change the amount he
    demands
  • no firm in the market has an incentive to change
    the combination of inputs it uses or to exit the
    market
  • no firm outside the market has an incentive to
    enter it
  • the aggregate supply equals the aggregate demand
  • extends short-run requirements by absence of
    incentives for entry and exit and capital
    expansion

20
  • if a firm makes extra-normal profits at the price
    that is determined by the intersection of
    aggregate supply and aggregate demand, and its
    optimal long-run level of capital and its profit
    maximizing quantity (i.e. where p long-run
    marginal cost), this will attract other firms to
    enter, which will shift the supply curve to the
    right (Fig 13.20)
  • the incentive for new firms to enter disappears
    when firms in the market do not make extra-normal
    profits, hence when the price equals the minimal
    long-run average cost (where they are equal to
    long-run marginal costs)
  • thus in long-run equilibrium firms use amount of
    capital that allows them to produce at minimal
    long-run average cost
  • The Long-Run Equilibrium for Heterogeneous Firms
  • if a firm has a lower cost due to a special
    factor, it earns an economic rent. Since this
    factor could be sold, the price the firm could
    obtain is the opportunity cost of using the
    factor including this opportunity cost in the
    total cost, the firm does not make extra-normal
    profits

21
  • Dynamic Changes in Market Equilibria
  • in the short run an increase in demand leads to a
    higher price, because the short-run supply curve
    is upward sloping
  • this implies firms in the market make
    extra-normal profits
  • this attracts new firms, which shifts supply
    curve right
  • if the industry has only a small share in the
    input markets, entry will not affect input prices
    (Fig 13.23)
  • entry does not change costs of existing or new
    firms
  • long-run supply curve is flat constant-cost
    industry
  • if supplying more inputs is increasingly costly,
    entry has a pecuniary externality on the market,
    because it increases cost for existing firms
    increasing-cost industry
  • long-run supply curve is upward sloping
  • if the supplier of an input has increasing
    returns to scale, prices for inputs can decrease
    by entry decreasing-cost industry
  • long-run supply curve is downward-sloping

22
  • Why Are Long-Run Competitive Equilibria So Good?
  • Welfare Proposition 1 Consumer and Producer
    Surplus Are Maximized
  • at any smaller quantity there is a dead-weight
    loss, at any larger quantity marginal cost
    exceeds willingness to pay
  • Welfare Proposition 2 Price Is Set at Marginal
    Cost
  • In long-run equilibrium of competitive industry
    price is at intersection of supply and demand and
    supply equals MC
  • Welfare Proposition 3 Goods Are Produced at the
    Lowest Possible Cost and in the Most Efficient
    Manner
  • If firms do not produce with the level of capital
    that minimizes average cost, they earn
    extra-normal profits that attract entry
  • Production is organized efficiently among firms
  • output shares are allocated such that all firms
    have the same marginal cost if C(qi)gtC(qk),
    the same output could be obtained at lower cost
    by decreasing qi and increasing qk

23
  • 13.2 Market Institutions and Market Equilibria
  • the analysis so far has been institution-free,
    ignoring the specific rules that organize
    behavior in different markets
  • does it depend on the rules that organize a
    market whether a market equilibrium is reached?
  • this has been investigated in thousands of
    experiments (notably by Vernon Smith, Nobel Prize
    Laureate 2002)
  • these experiments use induced demand and supply
    curves, i.e. buyers are paid by the experimenter
    a predetermined value for each (fictitious) unit
    purchased and sellers have to pay the
    experimenter a cost for each unit they sells
  • buyers have incentive to buy for a price as low
    as possible, sellers have incentive to sell for a
    price as high as possible
  • this allows the experimenter to compare
    experimentally different market institutions with
    exactly the same supply and demand schedules,
    hence isolating the effect of the market
    institution

24
  • examples for market institutions
  • double oral auction buyers and sellers shout
    bids and offers simultaneously and at any time
    each buyer or seller can accept the best standing
    offer or bid
  • one-sided oral auction only the buyers (or the
    sellers) can make bids (or offers) the sellers
    (or buyers) can only accept the best standing bid
    (or offer)
  • experimental results double oral auctions
    converge quickly to market equilibrium, one-sided
    oral auctions tend to favor the passive side
  • Note with upward-sloping supply and
    downward-sloping demand, the competitive
    equilibrium does not maximize the number of units
    sold, but it does maximize the total surplus

25
  • Other Auction Institutions
  • an auction is a market institution to sell (or
    buy) an object where potential buyers make bids
    and the outcome (who obtains the good and who
    pays how much) depends only on the bids
  • hence auctions are universal any object can be
    sold by any auction, and anonymous the result
    for a bidder does only depend on the bids, but
    not on his identity
  • examples
  • English auction bidders openly place increasing
    bids
  • Dutch auction price starts at high level and
    decreases until one buyer accepts
  • Sealed-bid auctions bidders submit written bids,
    highest wins
  • First-price auction winner pays his bid
  • Second-price auction winner pays second highest
    bid
  • Dutch and first-price sealed-bid auctions are
    strategically equivalent they define the same
    game choose a number, the highest number wins
    and the winner pays his bid

26
  • auctions can be differentiated into
  • private value auctions each bidder has an
    independent value of the object, knows only his
    own value (e.g. works of art)
  • (pure) common value auctions there is an
    objective value of the object, identical for all
    bidders value is unknown, but each bidder has
    some signal of this value (e.g. oil field)
  • Private Value Auctions
  • Outcomes in English and second-price auctions are
    identical in both it is a weakly dominant
    strategy to bid the own value hence the bidder
    with the highest value wins (thus they are
    efficient) and pays the second highest value
  • standard auction the bidder who bids the highest
    amount wins the object
  • Revenue Equivalence Theorem if bidders values
    are drawn independently from the same
    distribution and all bidders are risk-neutral,
    then all standard auctions generate the same
    expected revenue, which is identical to the
    expected second highest value

27
  • Common Value Auctions and the Winners Curse
  • winning a common value auction brings bad news,
    because it means that the other bidders had
    information that led them to a lower estimate of
    the value
  • not taking this into account leads to the
    winners curse, the winner of the auction pays
    too much
  • assume you are bidding with a thousand other
    people for a jar full of 20 CZK coins if
    everybody bids his or her estimate, then if you
    win, it is extremely probable that your estimate
    was too high and hence you make a loss
  • note that the winners curse does not occur in
    equilibrium equilibrium bids take it properly
    into account, by bidding the estimate of the
    value conditional on the own signal being the
    highest
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com