Horizontal Mergers - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 104
About This Presentation
Title:

Horizontal Mergers

Description:

We consider mergers between firms acting on the same market: horizontal mergers ... ET eliminates the pecuniary horizontal externality. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:344
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 105
Provided by: msea7
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Horizontal Mergers


1
Horizontal Mergers
  • Carmo Seabra

2
3.3.3. Mergers (Concentrations)
  • We consider mergers between firms acting on the
    same market horizontal mergers if the firms
    operate at the same production stage and vertical
    mergers between firms acting at different stages.
    Mergers between firms in different markets
    (clothing and beer...) are less likely to afect
    competition and will not be adressed.
  • Mergers may have very different sources
  • small firms trying to increase their rate of
    growth
  • One management group convinced it can enhance the
    value of a competitor
  • Firms with complementary assets trying to
    increase their efficiency
  • Firms trying to increase their market power

3
3.3.3 Horizontal Mergers
  • An horizontal merger should be evaluated on the
    basis of its
  • unilateral effects, or reinforcment of its single
    firm dominance and
  • pro-collusive effects or or joint dominance
    (coordinated effects) effects.
  • We have seen that collusion is always harmful to
    consumers and social welfare.
  • In the case of mergers, the implications to
    welfare are less clear in fact, usually a merger
    increases the market power or the dominant
    position of the merging firms, being detrimental
    to consumers and social welfare. But it may also
    happen that it increases efficiency

4
3.3.3 Unilateral effects of horizontal mergers
  • Unilateral effects or reinforcement of single
    dominance occurs when the merged firm does not
    coordinate its behaviour with its rivals firms
    behave non-cooperatively, both before and after
    the merger (art 12 of Law 18/2003)
  • Unilateral effects are of two types
  • Mergers tends to increase the market power of the
    merging firms, leading to an increase in prices
    and a decrease in consumers surplus and welfare.
    This has distributional and allocative negative
    consequences
  • This negative effect may be partially or totally
    offset by efficiency gains

5
3.3.3.Increase in market power
  • There is a decrease in the nº of participants,
    whose impact on the competitiveness of the market
    depends on the nº of competitors, on the
    dimension of the merging firms, on their
    strategies...
  • If firms compete on prices, (Bertrand) the merge
    leads to an increase on the price of the merged
    firm and of its rivals. Consumers welfare
    decreases.
  • If firms compete on quantities, (Cournot) then
    the output of the merged firm decreases (it
    raises its price) but the output of the rivals
    increase (reduce their price). However, overall,
    the effect on consumers surpluse is also negative

6
3.3.3.Increase in market power
  • As to profits, in general the merger should
    increase the profits of the merging firms, and
  • The profits of outside firms do increase, too. In
    fact, outsiders can gain even more than the
    merging firms themselves. (That is probably the
    reason why outsiders rarely complain of projected
    mergers)
  • Producers surplus unambiguously increases
  • However, it can be shown that welfare decreases,
    if there are no efficiency gains associated with
    the merger

7
3.3.3. Increase in unilateral market power
  • Concentration
  • the larger the of firms after the merger, the
    less detrimental it is
  • The lower the market shares of merging firms, the
    less detrimental to welfare the merger is and
    even without efficiency gains, a merger between
    two small firms may increase welfare. But mergers
    that increase the size of the largest firm or
    that create a new largest firm always decrease
    welfare
  • The relative productive capacities of all the
    participants if the rivals are not able to
    satisfy additional demand, the market power of
    the merged firm increases. Otherwise it
    decreases.

8
3.3.3. Increase in unilateral market power
  • - Remember the Concentration Index of
    Herfindahl-Hirschman (HHI)
  • More than the level of concentration, one should
    look at its change US agencies consider that
    mergers leading to values of HHI lower than 1000
    do not harm competition.
  • If post merger HHI is between 1000 and 1800
    (moderate concentration), the merger is allowed
    unless the increase in the value of HHI is larger
    than 100.

9
3.3.3. Increase in unilateral market power
  • If the value of the HHI exceeds 1800 after the
    merger, this will be allowed iif this values
    increase is not larger than 50.
  • Another indicator of the effect on competition
    of a merger between firms A and B is the change
    in the elasticity of the residual demand function
    e A,A e A,B this measures the effect on
    Ademand of a 1 percent increase in As price
    minus the effect on As demand of the same
    increase in the price of B. This difference
    expresses the market power of A, ie, when A and B
    coordinate their strategy and increase prices
    simultaneously, firm A will loose the consumers
    going to other firms minus those that would have
    gone to firm B

10
3.3.3. Increase in unilateral market power
  • Another relevant indicator of the market power of
    the merging firms is the diversion ration
    dAeAB/eAA the proportion of lost sales that is
    captured by product B when As prices increase,
    or the proportion of consumers that consider B
    their second best alternative to A
  • This ratio measures the intensity of pre-merger
    competition between A and B a small value of d
    means that A and B are not close competitors and
    the merge should not have a significant effect on
    market power
  • Under some conditions dAmB/1-mA meaning that
    the probability that B is the second best option
    to A equals the market share of B relative to the
    market share of all the participants with the
    exception of A

11
3.3.3. Other factors affecting the unilateral
impact of a merger
  • Entry the easier and less costly entry is, the
    lower the market power enjoyed by merging firms
  • Potential entrants that anticipated negative
    profits at the pre-merger price may become
    profitable after the merger this possibility may
    restrain the merging firm from increasing prices
  • The countervailing buyers power strong buyers
    limit the sellerss market power
  • This is true but does not imply that the lower
    prices are passed to consumers if the buyers
    market is in itself non-competitive ...

12
3.3.3. Other factors affecting the unilateral
impact of a merger
  • Switching costs increase market power
  • The failing firm defence a merger between two
    firms, one of which was comdemned anyway, does
    not hurt competition
  • If production depends on the availability of
    essential inputs, the access of rivals to those
    inputs is relevant.
  • Techonological innovation
  • The structure of the distribution networks

13
3.3.3. Efficiency Gains
  • Efficiency gains may outweight the increase in
    market power of merging firms and result in
    higher welfare (lower prices). These may be due
    to
  • Rationalisation savings from reallocating output
    from one facility to another, without changing
    joint output. (Marginal costs may be different,
    prior to the merger, due to different amounts os
    physical capital, different levels of knowledge,
    different output levels)
  • Economies of scale and scope
  • long-run economies of scale in production, RD
    and marketing and distribution). Notice that
    exploitation of economies of scale may imply a
    decrease in product diversity

14
3.3.3. Efficiency Gains
  • short-run economies of scale (due to elimination
    of indivisibilities in inputs, like billing,
    purchases of materials) this implies a decrease
    in fixed costs.
  • Technological Progress either process
    innovations or product innovations or quality
    improvements
  • Diffusion of know-how (either one way or two way)
  • Incentives for R D (too much competition could
    destroy the incentives for research, and a merger
    coul help the internalisation of benefits

15
3.3.3. Efficiency Gains
  • Purchasing Economies
  • If factor markets are imperfectly competitive
    the merger can increase welfare
  • The merger can have quantity discounts
  • Slack
  • Disciplining power of the capital market (threat
    of entry and a strict merger policy...)
  • When a merger has efficiency gains, and an
    overall positive effect on welfare, outside firms
    will always lose profits. Then, a possible test
    for expected efficiency gains associated with an
    announced merger is to look at competitors shares
    value

16
3.3.3.Efficiency Gains
  • if these decrease, economic analist predict an
    increase in efficiency of the merged firms (of
    course, these changes can also be due to wrong
    predictions, to speculation, to external shocks,
    to expectations relative to the competition
    authority decision -if CA is expected to prohibit
    the merger, even when it has efficiency gains,
    rivals' shares might even increase, due to the
    regulatory costs incurred by the merging
    firms...).
  • If outside firms complain about the
    anti-competitive effects of a merger, CA should
    treat those complaints with great scepticism
    (they can mean that they anticipate significant
    efficiency gains, that is, that the merger is
    welfare increasing).

17
3.3.3. Efficiency Gains
  • Notice that efficiency gains decreasing variable
    costs are more likely to affect welfare through
    price reductions and increases in consumers
    welfare, while efficiency gains affecting only
    fixed costs will not lead to price changes, but
    impact profits only.
  • Farrell and Shaphir argue that CA should consider
    only efficiency gains obtained by synergies ,
    intimate integration of the firmss unique, hard
    to trade assets while no-synergies efficiency
    gains, like those derived from mere
    reorganization of production among facilities,
    should be disregarded

18
3.3.3. Efficiency Gains
  • A problem with the consideration of efficiency
    gains is that they are usually hard to calculate
    and completely dependent on information
    exclusively hels by the firm
  • In assessing efficiency gains of a merger it is
    very important to show that these efficiency
    improvements could not have taken place in the
    absence of the merger
  • Efficiency gains should be computed net of costs

19
3.3.3.Pro-collusive effects of horizontal mergers
  • A merger may reinforce the incentives for
    collusion, or joint dominance, (coordinated
    effects).
  • The effect of efficiency gains in joint dominance
    is more difficult to analyse. In general, if
    efficiency gains result in lower costs or higher
    capacity, incentives to deviate increase (and the
    stability of collusion decreases). But if
    symmetry increases, incentives to form stable
    collusive agreements increase, the overall impact
    on welfare may be negative.

20
3.3.3.Remedies
  • The decision of competition Authorities
    concerning mergers can be Yes, No, or Yes But,
    imposing remedies for the merger to be allowed.
  • Remedies can be of two broad types
  • Structural, which change the ownership of
    property rights, i.e., may oblige the merging
    firms to sell part of their holdings (usually
    applied in network industries where the merger
    may create regional monopolies)
  • Behavioural impose some restrictions on the
    behaviour of the merging firms, in particular
    concerning the practice of foreclosure

21
3.3.3. Structural Remedies
  • Divestitures
  • If the merger is expected to have
    anti-competitive consequences on some
    geographical markets or product markets, the CA
    may order a divestment of assets
  • These assets can be acquired by an existing
    competitor or by a new firm, but the CA should
    require that the buyer is enabled with the
    conditions to become an active competitor all
    the elements required ...to act as a viable
    competitor..tangible (.RD, production,
    distribution, sales and marketing activities) and
    intangibles (such as intellectual prperty rights
    and goodwill) assets, personnel, supply and sales
    agreements, customer lists.....and so forth
    (Commission Notice on remedies, page 46)

22
3.3.3. Structural Remedies
  • Divestitures
  • The authority may also order divestiture of
    assets that do not represent an anti-competitive
    thereat, if there are economies of scale or
    network egffects
  • Problems with divestitures
  • Incentives of the sellers to decrease the value
    of the divested business, and to choose a
    non-effective competitor
  • Informational assymetries between seller and
    buyers the seller does not sell all of the
    inputs required for competition to materialise
  • Empirical studies have shown that if the buyer
    must continue to have a relationship with the
    seller, either they will collude or the buyer
    neves becomes an efective competitor
  • Buyers that intend to collude in the future will
    be willing to pay more for the assets have a
    larger probability of getting them
  • If symmetry increases, the outcome may be
    collusion

23
3.3.3. Behavioural Remedies
  • Commitments to guarantee a level-playing field on
    the use of assets, technologies, inputs
    (vertical firewalls, obligation of the merged
    firms to sell a technology or an essential input
    to entrant competitors ...)
  • A problem with these remedies is that they
    require a continuous monitoring and enforcement.
    Further, they are usually easy to evade, given
    that the CA lacks sufficiently detailed knowledge
    of the industry

24
3.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
  • Most empirical studies analysed the evolution of
    profitability accounting profits or shares
    prices. If these increase, either market power
    increased or there were efficiency gains, or a
    combination of the two. This type of evidence can
    not discriminate between the two effects.
  • Additional evidence on consumer prices, on the
    prices of the shares of the competing firms (if
    these increase, reinforcement of market power
    dominated) can help the distinction between these
    effects
  • There are also some empirical studies that tried
    to directly quantify efficiency gains

25
3.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
  • Limits
  • The nº of studies is very small
  • The evidence on company performance is
    contradictory
  • The majority of the studies concern
    manufacturing, in the 60s and 70s and in the USA

26
3.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
  • The empirical evidence on the profitability of
    mergers shows very clearly that the potential
    benefits from mergers are usualy exagerated and
    that its costs are often undervalued the market
    overestimates the ability of bidders to manage
    other companies assets
  • Mergers as managerial discipline the idea that
    mergers improve efficiency because less efficient
    managers tend to be substituted for more
    efficient ones has not been clearly proved by
    empirical analysis, too. Further , according to
    Matusaka (93) the market prefers bidders who do
    not replace the management of the acquired
    companies

27
3.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
  • Empirical analysis of the mergers on the US
    airline industry between 1985 and 1988 shows that
    merged firms tended to price higher than the
    others, suggesting that eventual inctreases in
    efficiency that might have taken place were
    outweighted by the reinforcment of market power,
    leading to overall welfare decreases.
  • Conclusions
  • Horizontal mergers seem to increase market power
  • There is no support for a general presumption
    that mergers create efficiency gains
  • In particular cases, however, there were
    segnificant efficiency gains

28
3.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
  • Profit flows studies mergers have but modest
    effects on the profitability of merging firms
  • If market power increases then the merger
    increases inefficiencies
  • Outsiders may gain more than merging firms dont
    have to reduce quantity and profit from the
    increase in prices
  • Studies of share prices The most puzzling result
    of this literature is the fact that, while
    profits decrease, share prices increase. The
    pre-emptive merger motive? The merger decreases
    profits compared to the status quo, but increases
    profits compared with the relevant alternative

29
3.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
  • The US Competition authorities have been quite
    strict in analysing mergers requiring
    extraordinarily large efficiency gains to allow
    it when there are potential adverse competitive
    effects.
  • The EU Merger Guidelines recognizes the role of
    efficiency gains on the appraisal of a merger,
    but the Commission until now has followed a more
    ambiguous approach. Indeed in same cases,
    efficiency gains were even considered a minus, in
    that they would hurt rivals.
  • However, in its present formulation, the approval
    of non competitive mergers on the grounds that
    they could create national champions, like France
    wanted, has not passed.

30
3.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
  • Criteria for (not) considering efficiency
    increases
  • Redistributive gains should not be considered
    saving in costs due to discounts from suppliers
  • Cost savings associated with quantity reductions
  • If the criteria is consumers surplus, cost
    savings in fixed costs, like administrative
    costs, should not be considered
  • Effects on other markets in Germany, the UK, and
    Portugal are considered while US courts do not

31
3.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
  • There are 3 basic approaches to the appraisal of
    a merger
  • Case-by-case analysis high informational costs
  • General presumption model, using general
    structural indicators high uncertainty costs,
    because empirical studies show that particular
    circumstances may have large impact on the result
    of a given concentration
  • Sequential approach in a first step, structural
    indicators are used to arrive at an initial
    decision. In a second phase an efficiency
    defence with a a more detailed investigation,
    is allowed

32
3.3.3. Summing-up
  • In the analysis of a prospective Merger, the CA
    must evaluate
  • Its anti-competitive effects
  • Eventual increases in efficiency
  • In general, mergers increase the welfare of the
    merging firms, but decrease overall welfare.
  • In the appraisal of the effects of a merger,
    attention must be taken with the problems of
    information asymmetry between the merging units
    and the authority
  • A possible solution is to look only at the
    effects of the operation on the welfare of
    consumers and outside firms, assuming that its
    effect on the welfare of the proponent is always
    positive

33
Vertical Restraints and Vertical Integration
  • Carmo Seabra

34
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Often a product goes through different stages of
    production and comercialization before reaching
    the final consumer
  • Vertical restraints are agreements and
    contractual provisions betweeen vertically
    related firms. These may be aimed at
  • Reducing transactions costs
  • Guarantee availability and security of supply...
  • Coordination...
  • These vertical restraints can take many different
    forms and in some circumstances they may have
    differentiated impact on welfare

35
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Vertical mergers have in common with vertical
    restraints the fact that they both aim at solving
    coordination problems
  • However these two problems receive a different
    treatment under Competition Law. In the EU,
    vertical mergers fall under the Mergers
    Regulation, while vertical restraints can be the
    object of art 81 (agreement between firms ) or of
    art 82 if the firm has a dominant position

36
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Example Consider a manufacturer and a retailer.
  • Due to an horizontal externality, the effort of
    the retailer associated with the sale of the
    output tends to be sub-optimal in fact, unless
    the retailer has the monopoly of the sale, his
    investments on the promotion of the good has a
    public good characteristic
  • This horizontal externality arises because the
    seller shares with other retailers the benefits
    of its efforts to increase sales, while the costs
    remain concentrated. Unless the manufacturer
    devises a mechanism to increase the benefits of
    the retailer, this ones investment will be
    sub-optimal

37
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • In order to lead the retailer to increase its
    efforts on the promotion of its sales, the
    manufacturer may pursue a set of possible
    policies such as
  • Give the retailer the exclusive of the sale, so
    that it has incentives to advertise the product
    without the fear of creating externalities to
    rivals
  • Practice non-linear pricing (a two-part tariffs
    including a fixed fee for access to the product
    plus a variable (low) price per unit sold this
    scheme is common in several brands of clothes

38
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Other possible policies are
  • Give the retailer quantity discounts or
    progressive rebates
  • Require the sale of a minimum amount or of a
    maximum amount (in this case not to allow for
    price decreases)
  • Lead the retailer not to sell competing brands,
    by exclusivity clauses
  • Practice resale price maintenance of several
    forms (RPM) (fixed, price ceiling, price floor)
  • Create exclusive territorial schemes
  • Adopt selective distribution policies (forbid the
    sale in supermarkets , for fear of decreasing the
    image)

39
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • These policies need not be available at the same
    time and their respective usefulness depends on
    the particular circumstances for instance, if
    the final price paid by consumers is not easily
    observable by the manufacturer, then RPM is not
    adequate...
  • If arbitrage is easy, these vertical restraints
    may be impossible to set. Arbitrage in turn
    depends on the relative costs of search, on
    transaction costs, on transport costs
  • Low transport costs eliminate the efectiveness of
    exclusive territory clauses...
  • An alternative is a vertical merger

40
3.3.3.Vertical Integration
  • Vertical integration involves the firm
    undertaking itself the various stages of the
    production/distribution process the integrated
    firm substitutes internal operations and
    transfers for what would otherwise be market
    transactions
  • Williamson stressed that a firm may have several
    motives other than reinforcment of market power
    to vertically integrate
  • Minimize the negative effects of uncertainty
  • Reduce the dependency of the firm on outside
    suppliers or buyers, particularly relevant if a
    particular production stage requires specific
    assets
  • Easen the solution of conflicts, that remain
    within the firm

41
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • The welfare effects of vertical restraints depend
    on whether the vertical relations are intra-brand
    or inter-brand
  • Intra-brand competition refers to markets where
    retailers sell the same product or brand
  • Vertical restraints affecting intra-brand
    competition are usually welfare-increasing they
    allow a better coordination of the vertical chain
    and do not harm competition
  • If there is a monopoly at each stage then
    vertical integration avoids double
    marginalization and is welfare increasing, in
    that it allows the internalization of this
    vertical externality

42
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Double Marginalization and vertical integration
  • Demand is qa-p
  • Firm U (upstream), the manufacturer, has unit
    production cost of c and sells to a retailer,
    firm D (downstream)
  • Firm D buys product from firm U at a cost w. Its
    comercialization cost is equal to zero and sells
    to final consumers at p
  • First firm U chooses the wholesale price, w
  • Second Firm D chooses p, given w

43
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • The problem of the downstream firm, under
    vertical separation, is
  • Max PD(p-w)q (p-w).(a-p)
  • FOC are p(aw)/2
  • (1) q(a-w)/2
  • PD(a-w)2/4
  • Now, firm U knows that the quantity of q it sells
    depends on w. So it chooses w such as
  • Max PU(w-c)(a-w)/2
  • FOC is w(ac)/2

44
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Substituting back in (1) one gets
  • psep(3ac)/2
  • PDsep (a-c)2/16
  • PUsep (a-c)2/8
  • PDsep PDsep 3(a-c)2/16

45
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Under Vertical integration, firm U sells directly
    to consumers. So it chooses p so that
  • Max Pvi(p-c)(a-p)
  • FOCgtpvi(ac)/2
  • qvi (a-c)/2
  • Pvi (a-c)2/4
  • gtVertical integration is unambiguously better
  • Prices are lower, since agtc or the market would
    not exist
  • Quantities are larger, because cltwgt
  • Consumer surplus increases
  • Profits are larger, too firm U can pay firm D at
    least the profit it has under separation
  • Overall welfare must increase

46
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • If a vertical merger is not possible, several
    alternative and equivalent vertical restraints
    can solve this vertical externality
  • A. Resale price maintenance, RPM
  • Imposing the final price ppvi(ac)/2, vertical
    profits are maximized. Their distribution between
    the 2 firms depends on the wholesale price, w. If
    firm U is stronger, it will set wpvi(ac)/2 and
    will keep all the profits. The higher is w, the
    higher the share of profits that goes to the
    upstream firm. The same will hold if the upstream
    firm sets a price ceiling p(ac)/2

47
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • B. Quantity Fixing, QF
  • Firm U may oblige firm D to buy qvi(a-c)/2, or
    qgtqvi. Again, the level of w, which determines
    the relative distribution of profits, depends on
    the bargaining power of the 2 parties
  • C. Franchise Fee, FF
  • Firm U makes firm D pay Fwq, and sets wc. Then,
    firm Ds problem is
  • Max PDff(p-c)(a-p)-F
  • The solution is ppvi(ac)/2, qqvi, because F
    does not affect FOC.
  • The distribution of profits depends on F, as PUff
    F, and PDff (a-c)2/4-F. If firm U has all the
    bargaining power it will set F(a-c)2/4

48
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Under uncertainty, this equivalence disappears.
    Suppose that the retailer is risk-averse. Then,
  • if uncertainty refers to demand, RPM is a perfect
    insurance mechanism for the retailer, and
  • if uncertainty affects costs, non-linear pricing
    improves his situation
  • Summing-up
  • Under double marginalization -a vertical
    externality- vertical mergers, RPM, QF, FF lead
    to higher welfare
  • When competition at the retail level increases,
    the price-margin at this level deceases and
    welfare improves Policies that decrease
    competition at the retail level, like ET or
    exclusive retailers aggravates the double
    marginalization problem

49
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Horizontal Externality
  • free riding on the provision of services like
    advertising may lead to the under provision of
    these services, which is sub-optimal for firm U
    and for consumers. Again vertical integrationa
    and some vertical restrictions can help solve the
    problem
  • Exclusive territories decresases the probability
    that each consumer visits several shops
  • Fix resale prices or setting price floors may
    allow retailers to recoup their investments
  • Vertical integration can again solve the problem

50
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Conclusions
  • Vertical integration and vertical restraints
    equivalent to it, (which lead to the same
    outcome) reduces prices and increases output
    welfare increases
  • Different types of restrictions are equivalent
    hence choice between them should depend on the
    particular circumstances (RPM is ineffective when
    prices are non-observable, ET is irrelevant if
    transport costs are too low...)
  • Then competition policy should not prohibit some
    of these practices while allowing the others

51
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Effect upon variety
  • Consider now that n is variable
  • under vertical integration there will be less
    stores an integrated firm when deciding whether
    or not to open a new store, will consider its
    effect upon the profits of the pre-existing
    stores
  • Consumer surplus will be lower, but overall
    welfare may still be higher because the fixed
    cost of the marginal firm is saved. (Too much
    competition can lead to excessive differentiation)

52
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • So vertical integration decreases prices, but
    decreases variety, too. But most models conclude
    that, under plausible assumptions regarding
    preferences increasing preference for variety-
    welfare increases
  • The main point is that vertical and horizontal
    externalities create an opportunity for welfare
    increasing vertical restraints
  • No prohibition per se should exist a rule of
    reason is more appropriate
  • When the two types of externalities are present,
    the internalization of both externalities
    requires the use of at least two instruments. An
    example is Exclusive territories ET Franchise
    fee FF

53
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • ETFF
  • ET eliminates the pecuniary horizontal
    externality. (There is no fear of a rival
    undercutting the price) and the non-linear
    contract FF solves the double marginalization
    problem (ET QF does also solve the vertical
    externality)
  • If competition is scarce, vertical restraints can
    also reduce welfare in order to attract new
    customers, a vertically integrated monopolist can
    over-invest in quality, for instance. Infra
    marginal consumers (who do not value extra
    effort) may be harmed and overal consumerss
    welfare may decrease

54
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Other efficiency reasons for vertical restraints
    and vertical mergers
  • Quality certification by some retailers has a
    value. If other firms can undercut these firms
    prices, no certification will occur Hence RPM or
    selective distribution policies may be welfare
    increasing
  • Exclusive contracts because of free-riding
    between products, can increase the level of
    service by retailers
  • Exclusive dealing may also increase competition
  • Restraints that promote specific investments
    long-term contracts may avoid opportunistic
    behaviour (a firm jumping out of the relationship
    after the other has done specific investments...

55
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Negative Effects of Welfare Restraints
  • The Commitment Problem if vertical restraints
    help a manufacturer to commit to high prices,
    they will be welfare decreasing
  • Consider a manufacturer who auctions a franchise.
    He would get the monopoly profit, P, if
    canditates believed they would remain the sole
    sellers in the area. But after having sold that
    right for P, the manufacturer has incentives to
    auction a second license, by P/2 anticipating
    this, no one will offer him P on the 1st stage
  • Most Favoured Nation clauses, MFN, make a
    commitment credible. Notice that EC
    anti-discrimination policies are equivalent to
    enforcement of MFN.

56
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Conclusions
  • Vertical restraints can deteriorate welfare if
    contracts are non-observable, the monopolist has
    incentives to renegotiate them and anticipating
    this, a retailer would not set a contract, which
    deprives the monopolist of its market power. ET
    and RPM can solve this commitment problem and
    decrease welfare.
  • Imposing non discrimination or transparency
    clauses solves the commitment problem

57
3.3.3.Vertical Restraints
  • Vertical restraints that affect only intra-brand
    competition are mostly welfare-enhancing they
    can solve the vertical externality problem and
    increase profits. In most cases they will
    increase consumers surplus, too
  • However, vertival restraints can decrease
    welfare, if they lead to an excessive production
    of services or when they solve the commitment
    problem (to high prices) of the monopolist
  • If the market-power of the firms upstream is not
    large, its effect is not serious

58
3.3.3.Inter-brand competition
  • Consider now several manufacturers and several
    retailers. Vertical restraints may play an
    anti-competitive role, detrimental to social
    welfare. Inter brand competition can be affected
    by vertical restrainst in different ways
  • 1-. Strategic effects of vertical restraints (it
    may be used to relax competition and increase
    profits)
  • 2- It may favour collusion RPM increases
    observability and may be used to sustain
    collusive agreements
  • 3- It may foreclose efficient entry or deny
    access to essential inputs
  • efficiency (double marginalization avoided) and
    competition may be affected in opposite
    directions and the net effect needs to be
    evaluated on a case by case.

59
3.3.3.Leverage and foreclosure
  • Exclusive dealing Since the 50s the Chicago
    school contested the possibility that exclusive
    contracts lead to foreclosure
  • Posner and Brock arguments
  • Consider 1 incumbent monopolist, a buyer and a
    potential entrant the buyer will not sign an
    exclusive dealing agreement with the incumbent
    unless it expects to gain. It may gain either
    because the incumbent is more efficient than
    potential entrants and sets lower prices or
    because it is compensated by the incumbent.
    Posner and Brock show that there will exist a
    compensation that leads the buyer to accept the
    contract only if the incumbent has lower marginal
    cost than the entrant.

60
3.3.3. Exclusive Dealing
  • The largest compensation that the incumbent will
    pay amount to area cipMAC, the lost monopoly
    profit
  • the minimum compensation required by the buyer
    will be area cipMAC, the loss in consumer surplus
  • gt If exclusive contracts are signed, they must
    entail efficiency gains, and should not be
    prohibited

A
pM
M
B
C
ci
ce
61
3.3.3.Leverage and foreclosure
  • Post Chicago School arguments
  • Exclusive dealing may have anti-competitive
    effects if by excluding a more efficient entrant
    the incumbent makes profit M and is able to
    increase its market power in other markets (a
    possible reason is to enjoy economies of scope,
    unavailable to the entrant) he could convince the
    buyer to accept the deal and use these to
    foreclosure the market
  • Other models stress other possible channels
    whereby a less efficient incumbent can
    foreclosure the market (a large number of
    uncoordinated buyers, for example)

62
3.3.3.Policy implications
  • Vertical restraints may be welfare-enhancing
  • Thus it is not desirable to have a fixed rule vs
    vertical arranjements a case by case analysis
    (rule of reason) should be used
  • Properly designed vertical agreements and
    contracts can lead to the same results as
    vertical mergers.
  • This implies that these practices should be seen
    as substitutes and given the same tratment under
    competition law enforcment

63
Predation and other Exclusionary abuses
  • Carmo Seabra

64
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses art 82
  • Exclusionary abuses behaviour by dominant firms
    that have a foreclosure effect on the market,
    i.e. which are likely to completely or partially
    deter entry or force the exit of
    rival.(monopolisation in the US, art 82 in
    Europe)
  • Foreclusure may
  • Discourage entry
  • Limit expansion
  • Encourage the exit of rivals from the market
  • That is, it does not require that exit actually
    takes place

65
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • Exclusion of rivals may be pursued through the
    practice of low prices, with the aim of deterring
    entry, by decreasing rivals anticipated
    revenues.
  • Predation can also assume the form of non-pricing
    predatory strategies, pursued by a firm with the
    objective of increasing rivalss costs.
    Over-investment, tying and bundling,
    incompatibility decisions, refusal to supply,
    exclusive dealing are examples of such mechanisms
  • This type of non-price predatory behaviour may be
    pursued by non-dominant firms, too

66
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • Foreclosure or predation may assume different
    forms
  • Horizontal foreclusure
  • Predatory pricing
  • Single branding rebates
  • Tying and bundling
  • Vertical foreclosure
  • Refusal to supply
  • Examples of equivalent behaviours
  • Contractual tying vs. a pricing strategy of high
    stand-alone prices in comparison with low bundled
    price for 2 products
  • Contractual exclusive branding vs. high rebates
    in single branding

67
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • Refusal to supply vs. high upstream price and low
    downstram (near to final consumers) prices
    (margin squeeze)
  • Predation
  • The theory of predatory pricing assumes that a
    dominant firm lowers its prices for a
    sufficiently long period to induce competitors to
    leave the market and/or to deter entry.
  • To be efective, the predatory strategy must imply
    significant losses to the rivals
  • If the entrants are as efficient as the
    incumbent, then this one will suffer losses, too.
  • Notice dominant firms may be kept from lowering
    prices, to avoid problems with the CA)

68
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • For predation to be a profitable strategy,
    incumbents must have a reasonable expectation of
    gaining exploitable market power in the future
  • To start a predatory behaviour, incumbents must
    also have conditions to survive to its
    competitors, either through greater cash reserves
    (deeper pockets), easiest access to capital
    markets or cross subsidization from other markets
    or other products.
  • In some conditions, predation in one product or
    geographic market can have profitable effects on
    other markets, through the enforcement of the
    reputation of being a tough competitor

69
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • This effect can be enforced by the realization of
    investments in (over)capacity in the period
    immediately before entry occurs excess capacity
    lowers prices and these investments could be seen
    as a credible commitment to fight.
  • In short, for the practice of a low price to be a
    predatory strategy, and not the result of fierce
    competition it must be shown that
  • The firm is dominant
  • It has the intention to exclude rivals
  • It is profitable to lower prices, because gains
    in the long rum will outweigh present losses

70
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • According to the theory, price predation, to be
    effective, should be difficult to identify. In
    fact, for it to be a rational strategy, the
    victim must be unsure that predation is occurring
    -otherwise it will not leave the market, knowing
    that prices will increase in the future.
  • Because of this, predation is hard to prove
  • There are some empirical papers trying to
    investigate predatory pricing behaviour McGee
    (1958) studied the Standard Oil Trust behaviour
    at the turn of the century, Burns studied the
    tobbaco trust in the US (1891-1906) Salop and
    White analysed antitrust litigation . Usually
    these analysis show that price predation is very
    hard to prove

71
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • The theory of predatory pricing has been
    criticized by some authors, that argued that
    predation is an irrational strategy.
  • In particular, McGee and Easterbrook argued
    that, given the incumbents market share,
    predation would be more costly to him than to his
    rivals, and that his costs would increase with
    the success of the predatory strategy.
  • Their main point is that this fact makes
    predation non- credible to competitors. The
    losses associated with the predatory strategy
    must be weighted against future and uncertain
    gains.

72
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • Those future gains are uncertain because there
    are a of factors that may render the strategy
    of deterring entry unsucessful the entrant may
    have celebrated long-term contracts with
    customers that will not allow it to disappear, or
    it may shut down and waite for the increase in
    prices.... And if the entrant in fact gives up
    entry, in the future other firms may come
    in..(but entry and exit have sunk costs..).
  • According to McGee, predatory pricing is
    irrational becauses a merger (if allowed) would
    be a better solution.

73
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • And why wouldnt a small firm, even if
    financially constrained, be able to explain the
    predatory strategy to its lenders, thus obtaining
    the necessary funds?
  • However note that for future acquisition, a
    strategy of predatory pricing aimed at lowering
    the acquisition price could be a good solution
    predation for mergers

74
3.3.3.Predation
  • Theoretical Explanations for predatory behaviour
    Imperfect Information
  • A. Reputation models (for future contacts) an
    incumbent may set prices below cost to signal
    that he is a strong competitor
  • B. Signalling models (limit-pricing), an
    incumbent may set prices below cost to to
    manipulate the beliefs of rivals and convince
    them that he is more efficient than he really is
    or to damage the market information available to
    the entrants (signal jamming)
  • C. Imperfect Financial Markets models financial
    distress increases the risk, and lenders know
    that the larger the distress the larger is the
    probability that owners and managers will engage
    in excessively risky stategies

75
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • Non-price predation, or raising rivals costs,
    concerns the abuse of judicial and/or
    administrative procedures in order to raise
    rivals costs
  • If prices stay constant, the predator gains
    market share, as the rival restricts output. If
    prices increase, the predators margin increases.
  • Predation can occur through an abuse of
    governnment procedures, including litigation and
    the misuse of licensing or regulatory
    authorities.
  • Creation of standards, government regulations,
    exclusionary rights to inputs or sales network
    (vertical restrictions), the denial of access to
    essential facilities, bundling and tie-in sales...

76
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • In all these cases the dominant firm is able to
    spread its costs over a larger output than its
    rivals increasing disproportionately their costs
  • Unlike predatory pricing, non-pricing predation
    does not presuppose a dominant position of the
    predator nor that it develops its activity in
    multiple markets
  • Advertising and innovation might also be used
    with a predatory objective.
  • Several of the strategies that may be of a
    predatory nature can also be the outcome of a
    vigorous competition from an efficient supplier.
    It is very important to distinguish these
    situations.

77
3.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
  • Mistaking predation for competitive pricing
    (false positive) is as problematic as mistaking
    competitive pricing for predation (false
    negative). Both errors create problems and
    inhibit competition
  • To prove a predatory pricing strategy it is
    necessary
  • To prove that costs are below a certain cost
    standard (marginal cost? Other?)
  • To prove the intention to exclude rivals
  • To prove the capacity of the predator to recoup
    the losses in the future

78
3.3.3.Tests of Predatory Pricing the Areeda
Turner
  • In 1975 Areeda and Turner, proposed, in the
    Harvard Law Review, a test to be used by courts
    on the definition of predatory prices, ie, on the
    proof that prices are below a cost standard
  • The test reflects the view of its authors that
    predation is rare and that should not be confused
    with vigorous and healthy competition. In fact we
    will see that under this test predation is hard
    to prove.
  • The test aims at protecting only firms that are
    as efficient as the incumbent.
  • The test focuses on short-term efficiency, rather
    than long-run.

79
3.3.3.Tests of Predatory Pricing the Areeda
Turner
  • Its first standard is marginal-cost, but
    recognizing that it is usually difficult to
    measure marginal costs, they use average variable
    costs as a proxy. (the relevant time period, is
    the duration of the low pricing episode)
  • Hence, according to the Areeda Turner test,
    prices at or above reasonably anticipated average
    variable costs should be presumed legal, and
    prices below average variable costs cost should
    be illegal. Prices above full costs should be per
    se legal.
  • In addition, costs associated with promotional
    spending designed at meeting competition, should
    not be included .

80
3.3.3.Tests of predatory pricing Posner and ATC
  • This test raised a number of criticism ...(this
    rule) produces a defendants paradise, a
    monopolists heaven
  • Posner argued that the long-run is the relevant
    period of analysis hence prices should be
    compared with long-run marginal costs. Given the
    unavailability of these, the test should use full
    average cost based on the operators records
  • The demonstration of a predatory pricing
    strategy would require the test that prices were
    below ATC, plus the demonstration of predatory
    motivation (sometimes on press statements of
    company officials ...), plus the existence of
    some pre-requisites.

81
3.3.3.Output Restriction rule
  • Pre-requisites are an initial showing by the
    plaintiff of the market availability to
    predation the predator works in more markets
    that the plaintiffs, markets are concentrated,
    entry is slow, fringe firms are few, the product
    is homogeneous...
  • Williamson argued that predatory pricing should
    be seen as a long run business strategy hence
    the marginal cost-based tests proposed by Areeda,
    although correct, are incomplete, because they do
    not take into account the post-predatory period.

82
3.3.3.Output Restriction rule
  • For instance if a dominant firm anticipates that
    entry may occur and that it will be subject to
    the average variable cost rule, it can over
    invest in the period prior to entry, expanding
    output and lowering prices without violating the
    rule.
  • These side effects of anti-predatory prices
    should be taken into account when designing
    policy. Otherwise equally efficient entrants
    could be forced out

83
3.3.3.Output Restriction rule
  • So he proposed to prohibit dominant firms to
    expand output in the 12 to 18 months after entry
    occurs.. This time should be sufficient for
    entrants to gain experience and customers. During
    this period, price could not fall below average
    variable cost, too. It it did, the firm would
    have to decrease output in order to increase
    price.
  • Besides proving that this rule would be better in
    terms of welfare, he also considered that it
    would be easier to implement, because it wouldnt
    require estimating average and marginal costs.
  • In general prices should cover long-run average
    costs,

84
3.3.3.Baumol and strategic predation
  • While Williamson focused on controlling output
    increases in response to entry, Baumol looked at
    price increases after the entrant has been driven
    out the market. He proposed that any price cut
    made in response to entry should continue after
    exit, for some 5 years. This way, he eliminates
    the incentives of the predator to suffer losses
    in the first period anticipating monopoly profits
    in the second period
  • This rule dispenses any cost accounts and would
    allow equally efficient firms to survive.

85
3.3.3. Scherer rule-of reason tests
  • Scherer argues that long-run allocative
    efficiency can not be guaranteed by a simple
    short-run cost-based test. He proposes a
    wide-ranging inquiry into the predators conduct
    and intentions.
  • He stands that long-run welfare may be maximised
    with prices above or below marginal costs,
    depending on the circumstances that depends on
    the relative efficiencies of the firms, the
    minimum efficient scale...
  • This proposal, of a wide ranging inquiry into the
    particular conditions of the market intentions...
    has regained attention in the EU

86
3.3.3.Phlips
  • He states that the Williamson and Baumol
    approaches could facilitate collusion, and that
    the Areeda Turner test is under-inclusive and
    difficult to apply he defended the idea of the
    inquiry.
  • The benchmark, ie, the normal competitive price
    would be the non-collusive profit maximising
    oligopoly price (The Cournot Nash solution)
  • The inquiry should aim at determining wether the
    conduct of the alleged predator had turned a
    positive entry valueinto a negative one

87
3.3.3. Two-tier Rule of Joskow and Klevorick
  • Joskow and Klevorick in a 1979 article proposed a
    two stage approach to predatory pricing. The idea
    is that the first thing to do is to assess wether
    predation is a workable strategy in the market
    where it allegedly occurred. This first phase
    should eliminate harassment suits and decrease
    the risks of false positive cases, ie, confusing
    competition with predation.
  • This initial analysis should comprise the
    analysis of
  • Short-run monopoly power (predators market
    share, larger than 60, and the elasticity of
    demand for its products)

88
3.3.3.Two-tier Rule of Joskow and Klevorick
  • Conditions of entry (capital requirements,
    consumers loyalty, learning curves, quality of
    information about the risks of entry)
  • Dynamic effects of competitors and entry (stable
    markets pose more problems than fast growing
    markets, incumbents very innovative are less
    problematic, prices responsive to changes in
    demand or supply condition are also less likely
    to induce predatory behaviour)
  • If this first phase analysis leads to the
    conclusion that predation is not likely to occur,
    no pricing rule should be applied

89
3.3.3. Two-tier Rule of Joskow and Klevorick
  • In the second stage, a broad inquiry into pricing
    should be conducted
  • Prices below average variable costs should be
    deemed predatory
  • Prices between average variable costs and
    average costs should be presumed predatory
  • Prices above total costs are presumed legal
    unless a price cut in response to entry was
    reversed within two years without a cost or
    demand based reason
  • The probability of recouping present losses in
    the future should also be taken into consideration

90
3.3.3.Conclusions
  • The predator should have some market power before
    predation takes place
  • There must be some cost-based measures against
    which prices are evaluated short run or lung
    run? Variable or total cost?
  • Most people agree that RD, advertising,
    management and all other cost should be included
    excluded are only capital costs atributable to
    Investment in land, plant or equipment, property
    taxes and depreciation on land.
  • When there is excess capacity due to a drop in
    demand, below full cost pricing is to be allowed
  • Intention to exclude is also important

91
3.3.3. Empirical anlysis of predatory pricing
  • A full treatment is very difficult and there is a
    strong suspicion that these claims are used to
    support competitors more than competition
  • Several things are required an assessment of the
    costs and financial resources of the incumbent,
    of entry barriers (tangible and intangible), the
    viability of the entrant, the actual conduct of
    the incumbent. In particular if there are no
    barriers to entry, a predatory pricing strategy
    is not credible
  • Recent antitrust experience shows that actual
    cases are relatively rare, or at least are
    difficult to prove. (In the EU there have only
    been a small of Commission decisions on Article
    82

92
3.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
  • The Commission issued in December 2005 a
    discussion paper setting out a framework for the
    analysis of exclusionary abuses under Article 82
    and inviting comments by 31 March 2006.
  • Depending upon the results of the public
    consultation, guidelines may eventually emerge .
  • The main objective is to give an economic content
    to the discussion of exclusionary abuses,
    recognizing that Application of Article 82 in a
    form-based way may lead to the prohibition of
    behavior undertaken by dominant firms that may be
    pro-competitive for example, it may lead to
    lower prices or increase inter-brand competition.

93
3.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
  • The Commission is giving priority to exclusionary
    abuses, as this type of abuse is seen as
    particularly harmful to competition. It intends
    to review its approach to exploitative abuses,
    such as excessive pricing
  • sets out a general framework for analysis of
    exclusionary abuses. This analysis is then
    applied to four of the most common types of
    abuse
  • 1) predatory pricing
  • 2) single branding and rebates
  • 3) tying and bundling and
  • 4) refusal to supply.

94
3.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
  • The Commissions approach is based on the
    following benchmarks
  • Pricing below average avoidable costs (AAC)
    will lead to a presumption of an abuse and the
    Commission will not need to further justify its
    finding of abuse. The dominant firm may present
    arguments to rebut this presumption, based on
    lack of foreclosure effect, lack of predatory
    intent and inability to recoup losses. Note
    however, that, in most cases, the AAC will
    coincide with the AVC.

95
3.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
  • o

PgtATC no PltAAC Yes Or PltLRAIC yes (to be
used instead of AAC, in sectors with high fixed
costs ATCgtPgtLRAIC ?? losses are recovered, entry
barriers...
MC
ATC
LRAIC
AAC
AVC
96
3.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
  • Pricing above AAC, but below average total costs
    (ATC) Such behavior will be an abuse where
    there is evidence that the pricing is part of a
    strategy to eliminate competition. Both direct
    and indirect evidence will be taken into account
    to evaluate the likelihood of a foreclosure
    effect in view of the scale, duration and
    continuity of the low prices.
  • The Commissions position is that it is not
    necessary to show evidence of actual recovery of
    losses incurred by the dominant firm. Barriers to
    entry will normally be sufficiently high to
    presume the ability to recoup.

97
3.3.3. The EC analysis of predatory pricing
  • Pricing below long-run average incremental costs
    (LAIC) LAIC (which will be higher than AAC or
    AVC) may be used as a benchmark instead of AAC in
    certain sectors or markets that have recently
    been liberalized, where fixed costs tend to be
    high and variable costs tend to be low.
  • Pricing above ATC This is not generally
    considered to be an abuse because a dominant firm
    that prices above its ATC should only eliminate
    its less efficient rivals. An abuse will only
    occur in exceptional circumstances where there is
    a clear exclusionary strategy (for example, by
    several collectively dominant firms).

98
3.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
  • Single branding
  • a dominant firm which uses single-branding
    agreements in relation to a significant part of
    its customer base will have a foreclosure effect.
  • The Commission will apply a more effects-based
    approach to single branding, and may consider
    evidence that foreclosure effects will not arise
    for example, if agreements are for a short
    duration or depending on the termination rights
    set out in the agreement. These arguments may
    have particular weight where goods are homogenous
    and other competitors have spare capacity.

99
3.3.3.Empirical anlysis of predatory pricing
  • RebatesThe Commission will look at the likely
    foreclosure effects of a rebate program. The key
    question for the Commission is whether an as
    efficient operator would be able to compete in a
    market where a rebate program is in place.
  • The Commission distinguishes between conditional
    rebates (those granted as a reward for certain
    purchasing behaviour) and unconditional rebates
    (which are applied regardless of the buyers
    purchasing requirements).
  • In relation to conditional purchases, the
    Commission will apply the following analysis

100
3.3.3.Empirical anlysis of predatory pricing
  • The Commission will calculate the effective
    price of the products given the level of
    discount given to a buyer. The lower the
    effective price as compared with the average
    price of the dominant supplier, the stronger the
    loyalty-enhancing effect.
  • If the effective price is above AAC,
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com