Purchase Commitments for Vaccines: Their Uses and Their Limitations - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 146
About This Presentation
Title:

Purchase Commitments for Vaccines: Their Uses and Their Limitations

Description:

... PowerPoint and supporting papers can be found at: www.economics.ox.ac.uk/members/andrew.farlow ... feedback: andrew.farlow_at_economics.ox.ac.uk. Based on: ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:74
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 147
Provided by: andrew208
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Purchase Commitments for Vaccines: Their Uses and Their Limitations


1
Purchase Commitments for VaccinesTheir Uses and
Their Limitations
  • Andrew Farlow
  • University of Oxford
  • Department of Economics, and Oriel College
  • BioDesign Institute
  • Arizona State University
  • 5 April 2005
  • This version 16 May 2005
  • This has been rewritten so as to be a stand-alone
    presentation
  • without need of a presenter.
  • A downloadable copy of this PowerPoint and
    supporting papers can be found at
  • www.economics.ox.ac.uk/members/andrew.farlow
  • The author very much welcomes feedback
    andrew.farlow_at_economics.ox.ac.uk

2
Based on
  • The Global HIV Vaccine Enterprise, Malaria
    Vaccines, and Purchase Commitments What is the
    Fit?
  • Andrew Farlow, Submission to Commission on
    Intellectual Property Rights, Innovation and
    Public Health, WHO, March 2005.
  • Forthcoming in Innovation Strategy Today.
  • An Analysis of the Problems of RD Finance for
    Vaccines And an Appraisal of Advance Purchase
    Commitments
  • Andrew Farlow, April 2004.

3
The problem
  • Over 40,000 people many of them children die
    every day in developing countries of infectious
    or parasitic diseases.
  • Many could be saved by access to already
    developed vaccines and drugs
  • A large proportion of the disease burden in
    such countries is unnecessary, since it could be
    reduced by the effective distribution of
    medicines that are currently available and
    inexpensive. International Policy Network
    Incentivising research and development for the
    diseases of poverty 2005 p17.
  • Barely more than 1 of total global
    pharmaceutical expenditure goes into the research
    and development of new products for diseases
    affecting 90 of the worlds population.
  • 10-15 of global pharmaceutical spending goes
    into RD, and barely 10 of this goes into
    diseases impacting 90 of the worlds population.

4
Recent strides
  • Large fresh funds to purchase currently existing
    vaccines and to roll out immunisation programs
  • The UK 1.8bn over 15 years
  • Bill and Melinda Gates foundation 750m
  • Norway 290m.
  • Proposed 4bn budget over ten years for
    Immunizations, via an International Financing
    Facility for Immunizations
  • Though this budget and immunization initiative
    could, and should, have been provided with or
    without the IFF possibility.
  • Launch of Global HIV Vaccine Enterprise in
    2004.
  • UK presidency of the G8 and EU this year
  • Big opportunityor lost opportunity?
  • Given the potentially controversial nature of
    the IFF proposal, policy makers also need to take
    great care that, in all their public
    pronouncements, the IFF is seen to the there to
    support the immunizations and never the other way
    around.

5
A spectrum of vaccines
  • Low or non-use of many already existing, already
    cheap or even practically costless vaccines.
  • Late-stage vaccines where most of the science
    is already known and a viable product is close
    to, or already at, hand.
  • Early-stage highly complex and difficult
    vaccines such as those for HIV, malaria, and TB
    where there are either no viable vaccines on
    the horizon or current candidates fall well short
    of 100 effectiveness, and many scientific
    difficulties remain.
  • Spectrum of vaccines often lumped together.
  • But, instruments needed for each case are
    different.
  • Nature of purchase commitments for each kind of
    vaccine also differs.

6
The role of purchase commitments
  • Long-term purchase contracts/commitments very
    advantageous for underused and late-stage
    vaccines.
  • Advance Purchase Commitments (APCs) for
    early-stage vaccines here argued much weaker and
    a great deal more problematic than is often
    suggested
  • The phrase Advance Purchase Commitment, APC, is
    used here, and not Advance Market, since the
    latter needs to be proven and not prejudged to be
    the case by the choice of language used. An
    inability of APCs to perform as if a market is
    central to many of the concerns here.
  • For early-stage vaccine RD, manufacture and
    access may even be harmed by the presence of
    prior precommitments (certainly as currently
    proposed) compared to alternative mechanisms.
  • Where does the boundary between the cases fall?

7
Lessons from vaccine introductions 1
  • Past vaccine introductions
  • Hepatitis B
  • Haemophilus influenzae type B (Hib)
  • Smallpox.
  • Recent purchase arrangements
  • African trivalent meningitis vaccine
  • Meningitis conjugate C.
  • Future late-stage vaccines
  • Pneumococcus
  • Rotavirus
  • Issues
  • Cost of manufacture
  • Safety issues
  • Epidemiology.

All these case-studies are treated in detail in
Farlow, March 2005, Section 3.
8
Lessons from vaccine introductions 2
  • None of these case-studies remotely matches
    anything being proposed for HIV, malaria, and TB.
  • Many of the problems caused/resolved by contracts
    are very different for these case-studies
    compared to early-stage vaccines.
  • Case-studies illustrate current faults in need of
    rectification.
  • Current short-run contracts are inefficient a
    stable long-term market matters.
  • Get rid of market risk
  • The need for distribution commitments,
    vaccine/health infrastructure commitments and
    commitments to tackle market risk at many levels
  • APCs (as currently designed) for early-stage
    vaccines put market risk back on to developers!

9
Lessons from vaccine introductions 3
  • Good information on how to efficiently set terms
  • Information extracted through competitive
    tenders, etc.
  • Relatively easy to make the incentive
    additional via procurement contracts, etc.
  • Commitments as coordination devices.
  • In practical cases, the breakthrough was through
    lowering production costs
  • Incentives/competition for this?
  • Technological shifts dependent on access to
    technology, IP, know-how, especially at
    manufacture and distribution stage
  • Volume and regulatory issues important in
    lowering costs.

10
Lessons from vaccine introductions 4
  • Incentives to install capacity quickly and for
    use quickly.
  • Product differentiation and correcting vaccine
    market distortions.
  • Ability to use IP in ways to encourage
    competition, to keep the market open to many
    potential developers and producers, and to help
    create cheaper-to-produce vaccines.
  • Wider finance in place for a wider set of
    players
  • More open to those who cannot draw off deep
    pocket finance for long periods.

11
Lessons from vaccine introductions 5
  • Importance of role of developing/emerging country
    developers and manufacturers.
  • More ability to share information and collaborate
    (key for HIV? Malaria? TB?).
  • Relatively low levels of capital costs
    (compared to, e.g. case of HIV vaccines).
  • Lower risk to biotechs.
  • Many of these reasons are fungible they apply
    whatever the source of finance.
  • Not committee-driven over long horizons.
  • Current purchases do matter a lot.

12
Hepatitis B case-study
  • Hepatitis B case-study in draft versions of the
    recent CGD report dropped from final report.
  • Hepatitis B case does not support the reports
    underlying hypotheses for HIV/malaria/TB
  • The original Hepatitis B vaccine developers were
    not the ones who developed and maintained the
    lower price market
  • The competitive situation for hepatitis B today
    a key component in achieving long-term
    sustainable low prices reflects poorly on the
    lack of competition at a similar stage in product
    life cycle in the CGD report
  • Emphasis in the success of the Hepatitis B case
    on market and competitive devices to push
    production prices lower compared to
    insufficient emphasis in CGD report.

13
Why the sudden interest in HIV, malaria, and
tuberculosis? 1
  • Focus of attention increasingly on speculative,
    experimental applications to HIV, malaria, and
    tuberculosis, even though APCs never been used
    before for even the most basic of applications.
  • Less than a year ago these difficult vaccines
    were not deemed likely doable by this approach
  • Including by many now heavily advocating the
    approach.
  • By definition APCs cannot be tested except
    through trying
  • Should crash test the thinking, subjecting it
    to the harshest of possible self-critiques before
    trying
  • Given the risks of abandoning the approach due to
    lack of industry response and the constant need
    to change the program, should learn by trying
    less complicated vaccines first and building up
    to more complicated vaccines.

14
Why the sudden interest in HIV, malaria, and
tuberculosis? 2
  • Supporters and critics all concerned with
    incentives and rewards for private firm
    involvement.
  • Disagreement is about
  • The shape and timing of incentives and rewards
  • The ability to set APC terms remotely
    efficiently
  • Whether APCs will actually work as proposed
  • The role of, and interaction with, other parts of
    the overall mechanism for developing these
    early-stage vaccines
  • Order of priority, given the burden APCs place on
    the system capacity' of GAVI/VF/WHO, and use of
    political capital
  • The dangers of perverse results.
  • BIG CONCERN Approach feeds off (and also feeds)
    growing budgetary pressures to cut Vaccine RD
    funding especially for HIV given global
    fiscal deterioration.

15
Literature on this as an RD incentive for
early-stage vaccines
  • Making Markets for Vaccines (henceforth MM in
    all references), Center for Global Development
    (henceforth CGD), Washington, D.C., April, 2005.
  • Strong Medicine Creating Incentives for
    Pharmaceutical Research on Neglected Diseases,
    Kremer, M, and Glennerster, R, Princeton
    University Press, November, 2004.
  • UKs No. 10 Policy Unit 1998-2001.
  • Mostly the work of a small handful of authors.

16
Benchmark as an RD incentive for early-stage
vaccines 1
  • (These details taken from MM)
  • Legally binding contract before vaccine RD
  • Sponsor(s) and all actual and potential vaccine
    developers sign-on to the contract within 36
    months of the initiation of the program
  • All actual and potential developers agree to be
    monitored by the committee controlling the
    program
  • Later entry of developers policed by the
    committee
  • Those conducting current vaccine trials and
    failing to sign-on, and those initiating future
    vaccine trials without prior permission from the
    committee, are barred access to the eligible
    markets controlled by the committee
  • Sponsors have an opt-out if contract fails to
    stimulate enough research (though current
    status of opt-out is a little unclear).

17
Benchmark as an RD incentive 2
  • ISSUE Inability to identify all developers in
    advance.
  • ISSUE Highly complex and evolving vaccine
    development process that is also moving
    increasingly toward emerging/developing country
    developers.
  • How to avoid biasing early-stage APCs too early
    in favor of large developed-country companies,
    stymieing this evolution, and forcing later
    entrants to work through current large
    multinationals?
  • Opt-outs and sunset clauses hard to incorporate
    without feeding back to harm RD incentives.

18
Benchmark as an RD incentive 3
  • Sponsor(s) commit 3bn-10bn per disease
  • Figure keeps falling. Now 3bn each for HIV,
    malaria, and TB (This presentation sticks to
    original figures for now).
  • For the purchase of a vaccine or vaccines in a
    pre-agreed quantity (200-300 million treatments)
  • Figure keeps falling. Now 200 million each for
    HIV, malaria, and TB.
  • Benchmark has changed over last year. Prior to
    May 2004 a simple flat subsidy on each of the
    first X million of a vaccine.
  • Now a complicated subsidy spread over first X
    million of several possible vaccines
  • Rules for this unclear?and un-write-able?
  • But this is largely a change in language
  • Recent malaria announcements seem to target one
    vaccine.

19
Benchmark as an RD incentive 4
  • To aid credibility, sponsors relinquish control
    of their funding to a committee with
    discretionary powers.
  • Supposedly (since extremely difficult, if not
    impossible, to do in any practical sense for
    vaccines such as HIV, malaria, and TB) the size
    of (and distribution of) funding for the first
    200m high-cost treatments over developers is set
    precisely high enough to re-create the precise
    size of additional market needed to encourage
    the entry of the precise amount of venture
    capital and stock market finance needed for the
    remaining research and development including
    capital cost (though remaining is unclear)
    needed to produce a high quality vaccine or
    series of vaccines.
  • A complex expected subsidy pattern across
    developers and over time (investors
    expectations of this are key).

20
Benchmark as an RD incentive 5
  • All RD costs repaid through the purchase of a
    successful vaccine or (since May 2004) several
    vaccines in a particular period in time (if there
    are several meeting eligibility conditions in
    any period of time), or series of vaccines over
    time (to combat resistance perhaps and to give
    incentives for follow-on innovation), and only
    the successful vaccine(s) or series of vaccines.
  • This program (supposedly) funds additional
    eligible market purchases only
  • Eligible and non-eligible markets are
    separatedsomehow.
  • Repayment of RD costs is from taxpayers of
    richer countries, foundations such as the Bill
    and Melinda Gates Foundation, and through
    co-payments made by developing countries
    themselves (that may come from third parties)
  • The program is foundation- and publicly-funded.

21
Benchmark as an RD incentive 6
  • NOTE Overall cost of vaccine development should
    include all funding needed outside of the
    program, including subsidies, tax-breaks, and
    other benefits granted for research, and the
    spending of national governments and foundations,
    and any costs of vaccine enterprises.
  • An APC for HIV is likely to cover only a very
    small portion of the overall costs of HIV vaccine
    development.
  • This is ignored (so far) in CGD cost
    effectiveness calculations for early-stage
    vaccines
  • All DALYs saved are apportioned to the purchase
    commitment even if it will represent only a small
    portion of the overall cost of development of an
    HIV vaccine.

22
What the winner gets
  • (Supposedly) winner(s) repaid all of the
    privately-funded (and only the privately-funded)
    RD costs (including all capital costs) of all
    firms (both the successful and the unsuccessful)
    and only the private firms, who used such private
    funding on RD towards the vaccine since the time
    the purchase commitment had been announced (and
    only since the announcement) and only for
    eligible markets covered by the mechanism.
  • Capital costs refers to the costs of the
    finance used, and includes the required return to
    cover all risk being borne, including any risk
    created by the mechanism itself (i.e it does not
    refer to physical real capital investment).
  • Very different pricing strategies in eligible
    and non-eligible markets.
  • Firm gets all IP to the vaccine (under current
    proposal).

23
Problems with underlying model 1
  • Underlying (Kremer Appendix 3) model driving the
    logic for early-stage vaccines is highly
    simplistic. The critique here is that highly
    idealized perfectly-functioning APC models are
    contrasted with highly imperfect alternatives
    thus generating unfair comparisons, and not that
    alternatives are not themselves highly imperfect
    too.
  • The science is fixed, simple, constant, static,
    linear
  • Extremely simple probability structure.
  • No patents on anything other than end vaccine
    products
  • No financial constraints, investment hold-ups,
    strategic behaviors, constraints on flows of
    information, or concentrations of market power
    based on IP ownership
  • CASE When the Malaria Venture Initiative (MVI)
    mapped the patent status of the MSP-1 antigen,
    it found 39 different families of patents with
    monopoly scope impinging on it
  • No notion of near market or near scratch
    developers.

24
Problems with underlying model 2
  • No benefits in sharing information across vaccine
    developers. No know-how monopoly
  • Not good for describing projects involving
    science with lots of feedback loops,
    collaboration and the sharing of information
    (HIV, malaria, and tuberculosis vaccine
    research)
  • Lots of incentive to hoard information
  • CASE Existing developed economy patent holders,
    facing a potentially emerging-economy competitor,
    can exploit secret know-how (as well as more
    general technical know-how, and undisclosed test
    or other data), including refusing to contract to
    transfer necessary know-how, thus creating a
    barrier to entry. Given the mechanism for
    distributing payments, there is a strong
    incentive to hold out under APCs
  • Lack of know-how (extremely important for
    biological products) makes many disciplining
    threats non-credible (e.g. compulsory licenses if
    vaccine developers refuse to supply).

25
Problems with underlying model 3
  • No variation in the probabilities of discovery
    over the vaccine development process
  • No easy or difficult stretches of science.
  • No ways for technology to improve or deteriorate
    over time
  • No technology shocks,scientific breakthroughs
    or deteriorations
  • No need to incentivize such breakthroughs.
  • No sunk costs.
  • No large incumbent firms instead perfect
    competition everywhere and always.
  • No strategic behaviour of any sort, and of any
    firm, based on sunk costs, patent ownership,
    finance, or any other real-world factor.

26
Problems with underlying model 4
  • Extremely good understanding of the state of
    current and future (extremely simple) science.
  • No coordination problems across public and
    private sectors in their research decisions at a
    single point in time and over time.
  • No coordination problems across public and
    private sectors and all countries in their
    vaccine purchase decisions and in their provision
    of vaccine delivery systems.
  • An idealised, non-cyclical, set of financial
    markets.
  • No pipelines of products, no problems with
    vaccine resistance.
  • No composite vaccines, and no therapeutic
    vaccines.
  • Wide range of delivery issues ignored.
  • APCs need to be designed to handle/avoid these
    issues.

27
Some very rough HIV figures 1
  • 10 firms put in equal effort on an early-stage
    HIV vaccine (we maintain the fiction of
    competition for now that the program encourages
    competition needs to be proved).
  • Presume this is the optimal number of firms (we
    cant).
  • Expected 70 of capital costs (a guess - no
    figures releasedbut presumed high for an HIV
    APC).
  • Presume one firm wins (supposedly, several
    could).
  • 6.25bn (pre-April 2005 figures) goes to a firm
    having spent, in present discounted (2005) terms,
    less than 200m, on private out-of-pocket
    research costs (this is a figure for purely
    illustrative purposes).
  • This is the efficient and fair outcome and not
    being critiqued hereBut it does create problems
    for firms and the committee running the program,
    as we will see later.

28
Some very rough HIV figures 2
  • With no crowding out, the 6.25bn pays for
  • 1.875bn of out-of-pocket HIV RD costs across
    all firms
  • 4.375bn of capital (i.e. finance) costs.
  • With 50 crowding out (explained below) and
    other inefficiencies, the 6.25bn would pay for
  • about 900m of new out-of-pocket research costs
  • about 9 months worth of what those working on
    the Global HIV Vaccine Enterprise say is actually
    needed.
  • The most likely response of firms no response
    at all?
  • Again, these figures are very rough, and for
    illustrative purposes only.

29
Some very rough HIV figures 3
  • We can look at HIV from another angle.
  • HIV vaccines likely to take a minimum of 15 years
    to develop.
  • 1.2bn per year of out-of-pocket research and
    trial costs needed (IAVA 2004), i.e. double the
    current level.
  • Replacing this flow for 15 years with an APC at
    the end, would cost
  • 85bn (if required nominal rate of return 20)
  • 130bn (if required nominal rate of return 25)
  • Uncertainty about ever getting a vaccine is
    embedded in capital costs
  • Crowding out would make the figures worse
  • Reputational risk would make the figures worse.
  • These are low rates of return by venture capital
    standards, and exclude the (still likely very
    high) costs after 15 years.

30
Some very rough HIV figures 4
  • So, where does the MM figure of 3bn come from?
  • Where does the notion of multiple developers come
    from?
  • Need for a mega-blockbuster if using APC route
    for HIV?
  • Maybe this is why private firms currently spend
    so very little on HIV vaccine research in spite
    of there being a sizeable extant market for some
    clades of HIV?
  • How large are politicians prepared to make APC
    funds for HIV vaccines?
  • Are they prepared to massively top up later?
  • Is it realistic to believe that funding levels
    for such programs for HIV will be set high enough
    with no pressure to readjust firm payoffs down
    later?
  • All MM cost effectiveness figures are worked out
    on basis of the 3bn and not on the basis of
    these much larger figures for HIV.

31
Some very rough figures for firms
  • For a vaccine costing 25 per course of
    treatment, the best-case scenario (no crowding
    out, but high capital costs) is
  • 1-2 for production and distribution
  • 6-7 for private out-of-pocket RD costs
  • 16-18 for the cost of finance.
  • With 50 crowding out
  • About 3 for new private out-of-pocket RD costs.
  • But it is not clear that an HIV vaccine could be
    manufactured for a dollar or so (especially in
    early days)
  • Previous experiences with vaccine introductions
    suggest problems
  • Too little manufacturing competition to drive
    prices that low
  • IP held in too few hands
  • Ex ante worries that this will be the case, will
    undermine incentives to do RD in the first place
    (More on this below).

32
Figures for currently existing and late-stage
vaccines
  • The above are very, very rough figures, since
    paucity of information is such that we really do
    not have much of a handle on these issues.
  • We can say, however, that the above proportions
    are completely the converse for currently
    existing vaccines, and, indeed, for many
    late-stage vaccines
  • Much lower capital costs because of much lower
    risk, especially risks of the mechanism itself
  • No crowding out (because of the ability to use
    competitive tenders and other separation
    devices)
  • Much more easy to set efficient terms (because of
    competitive tenders and other devices to reveal
    information, and good information on technology,
    etc.).

33
Impossible to set size efficiently
  • Each APC should be set commensurate with the
    difficulty of the underlying science and the cost
    of the RD of developing the vaccine at hand.
  • MM suggests 3bn per disease for HIV, malaria,
    and TB. Setting this right is a crucial detail
    (MM April 2005)
  • For no obvious reason, the figure is much lower
    than in draft versions of the report (of even
    just a few months ago)
  • Though this was recently described, though not in
    MM itself, as for illustrative purposes only.
  • Needs a methodology based on expected
  • Complexity of underlying science
  • RD costs (also depending on types of firms
    encouraged)
  • Epidemiology
  • Production costs, etc.
  • NOTE Not just information on the medical
    condition itself.

34
Not a good idea to base on typical market size
  • An auction and heavy monitoring suggested to
    set size
  • Couldnt work so abandoned.
  • Now size based on typical market size of new
    drugs and heavy monitoring to check firms are
    investing enough
  • Implicitly this means that the size is based on
    the typical costs of developing such drugs,
    since, in equilibrium, investment in drug
    development should be driven to the point where
    this is the case
  • This methodology is therefore essentially random
    for these early-stage vaccines
  • Overestimates (per unit) innovation costs of
    developing and emerging country innovators, even
    as they struggle to take advantage of APCs, even
    as it underestimates eventual costs if dependent
    on APC and developed country developers.

35
Setting size too high is wasteful
  • Racing, duplication.
  • Even less incentive not to share information.
  • Rent-seeking/lobbying/corruption.
  • Reduced resources made available for other
    vaccines and treatments, sanitation, nutrition,
    housing, etc.
  • If using an International Financing Facility,
    IFF, overly-high (and overly-low) APCs add to the
    risk the IFF bears.
  • Extra deadweight losses of taxation and the
    opportunity cost of the other projects that
    foundations, governments, and the IFF are
    prevented from doing.
  • If firms are not perfectly competitive,
    shareholders gain something (ceteris paribus)
    but at the expense of neglected diseases and
    other poverty alleviation projects.

36
Other reasons for overpayment
  • Me-too drugs/vaccines partly discipline
    patented drug/vaccine prices.
  • For purchases of underused vaccines, price
    disciplined by competitive tender, competition,
    access to IP, etc.
  • These disciplining devices are lost under APCs
    for early-stage vaccines.
  • Discipline in APC via committee and pre-agreed
    rules
  • But pre-agreed rules are hard to set and to
    credibly follow through.
  • RESULT Higher payment for given (lower) quality.
  • Self-fulfilling incentive ex ante also to work on
    lower quality.
  • There is also an additional ratchet effect No
    adjustment downwards if RD costs are reduced by
    technological advances or by improved publicly
    funded initiatives, etc.

37
Setting size too low is wasteful 1
  • Get no, or too little, extra private funding into
    RD.
  • Can raise size at the rate of interest rate. But
    no faster
  • Raising the size of the APC acts like an extra
    discount factor
  • Early investment becomes even more expensive
  • Firms delay investment.
  • But the rule about raising size is difficult to
    set
  • How is the start level chosen?
  • How is the speed of rise set?
  • How is judgment made that not enough investment
    has taken place, without good monitoring and
    given that the result on which to base judgment
    is only provided at the end?
  • Are politicians willing to sign on to such
    open-ended programs?
  • Current CGD thinking is that this is too
    difficult (or politically unacceptable), and this
    is not planned (or CGD are not yet saying how
    later re-adjustment will happen).

38
Setting size too low is wasteful 2
  • Development costs highly uncertain.
  • CGD after a long deliberation process did not
    narrow down beyond the range of 15-25 per
    treatment
  • The upper bound being 167 of the lower bound.
  • If size starts, optimistically, at the bottom of
    the range when actual costs are at the top of the
    range, and 10 interest rate it takes 8 years
    till APC has any effect (or it collapses first).
  • If real RD costs also grow at 5 per year
    (starting at the optimistic end of range) it
    takes 15 years to have any effect.
  • Consequence is delay, and strong pressures
    towards poorer quality (broadly defined) at any
    given APC size in order to get a result.
  • Maurer S. The Right Tool(s) Designing
    Cost-Effective Strategies for Neglected Disease
    Research, Goldman School of Public Policy,
    University of California at Berkeley, March 2005.
    Figures on this page from Maurer paper.

39
Some too high, others too low
  • Some vaccines set way too low. Get no or little
    response
  • 3bn for HIV? No connection to reality?
  • Overconfidence in ability to revise upwards
    later?
  • Other vaccines set too high and wasteful.
  • Other cases, strong incentive to head for more
    limited quality
  • Current malaria vaccine policy?
  • We never get to see the good outcomes that we
    never get because of poorly-set initial terms.
  • Overall a poor deal compared to alternatives?
  • It depends on how well alternatives cope with
    incentivizing effort, and dealing with failures
    in vaccine RD portfolios.
  • Yet, funder of program reserves right to abandon
    the mechanism if it is not working enough?

40
Getting it wrong for HIV?
  • If scientific complexity means that RD costs
    are much higher for an HIV vaccine than for other
    medicines, then 3bn may be too low to stimulate
    sufficient investment Note that, if the
    commitment is too small to stimulate industry
    investment, and therefore does not succeed, there
    is no cost to sponsors.
  • CGD FAQ sheet, April 2005.

41
Would a 3bn HIV purchase commitment simply
collapse?
  • Political limits to a program without any effect
    (especially if high transactions costs to GAVI,
    Vaccine Fund, WHO, and others of setting up and
    running the program).
  • Collapse is self-fulfilling (investors will not
    trust that any early investment will yield a
    payback, so dont bother).
  • Collapse incorporates cases where to avoid
    litigation the mechanism does nothing but
    sits ready to activate even if very destructive
    meanwhile after an alternative approach has
    been successful.
  • Worse if other approaches have stalled to make
    room for this approach.
  • The sole criteria of the (political) willingness
    of sponsors and recipient governments to pay (MM
    p52, word inserted) for dictating the size
    chosen, is a non-criterion.

42
More pay-as-you-go better?
  • This suggests more pay-as-you-go may be more
    capable of adapting to changing environment and
    less likely to fail to get a result (if set too
    low) or to overpay (if set too high).
  • It depends on how good PPPs and others can be
    made at dropping failing projects.
  • Note, alternative approaches still potentially
    include commercial involvement.
  • Current low levels of commercial involvement in
    PPPs is more a fault of the shoestring funding of
    PPPs than of any specific failings of PPPs.

43
Technical requirements in advance? 1
  • it would be possible though complicated to
    agree to product requirements in advancea small
    number of public health experts were concerned
    that it would be difficult to establish in
    advance technical requirements that a vaccine
    would need to meet. MM March 2005 p58, and final
    report.
  • Some set of technical requirements always
    possible.
  • But efficiency of those technical requirements
    requires some notion of the underlying
    feasibility of HIV, malaria and tuberculosis
    science, the potential costs of manufacture and
    distribution, epidemiology, etc. (i.e. many
    factors, and not just medical issues).
  • So fixed enough to avoid the danger that the
    sponsor would renege, but flexible enough to
    accommodate contingencies that were not foreseen
    at the time the rules were established. MM March
    2005 p43, and final report.

44
Technical requirements in advance? 2
  • Shifts problem to a different level of having a
    good notion of potential unforeseen contingences
    when setting the original rules.
  • An inability to set efficient technical
    specifications for each vaccine far in advance
  • Potential for great deal of discretion and
    interference later
  • Risk that term-setters are unwilling to admit
    they got it wrong and to reset the terms more
    efficiently later (though they can only correct
    themselves in the downwards direction)
  • Risky for all developers, but more so for some
    than for others
  • Most risky for those unable to influence the
    committee
  • It is expectations of all of this that matter to
    investors.

45
Minimum vaccine requirements 1
  • Minimum vaccine requirements set at the start
  • But, an efficient technical specification,
    closely resembling the eventual possible vaccine,
    would be impossible to set so far out for HIV,
    malaria, and tuberculosis.
  • Discretion of as few as four members of a
    committee to grant waivers and make
    modifications (MM April 2005) but only to lower
    those requirements never to raise them.
  • This asymmetry is bad policy in light of future
    possible improvements in science and possible
    future epidemiology.
  • But symmetric ability to raise requirements as
    well as to lower requirements creates risks for
    firms, and is irreconcilable with the current MM
    mechanism.
  • A dilemma.

46
Minimum vaccine requirements 2
  • Constant pressures to lower the minimum
    acceptable requirements towards the very lowest
    level of any epidemiological value.
  • In successive drafts of MM, malaria vaccine
    requirements gravitated ever-lower
  • Final report 50 efficacy for 24 months from up
    to four doses
  • This requirement (and the 3bn size) was recently
    described as for illustrative purposes only.
  • A program that militates against the development
    of useful vaccines that far exceed minimum
    requirements?

47
Problems setting the long-term price
  • Contracts call for determination, at the time of
    signing, of the guaranteed long-term price, or
    of an ex ante methodology for determining the
    long-term price.
  • Legal obligation to supply at this price in the
    long-term in return for having had the short-term
    advantage of initial sales at very high, heavily
    subsidized, guaranteed prices.
  • The 3bn is payment, in part, for this.
  • A critical component of the advance market
    commitment (MM report April 2005) and key to its
    claim as the way to end ten to fifteen year
    delays in access to new vaccines.
  • No such methodology for setting long-term price
    exists (see NIH evidence).
  • CGD advised price could range from 0.50 to
    15.00, and that no such guarantee could be
    inserted into contracts.
  • Left blank in MM contract term sheets.

48
What if firms wont/cant supply? 1
  • Firm can always refuse to supply at short-term
    price (e.g. in order to supply a more lucrative
    market for HIV first).
  • If cost not low enough, or firm prefers not to
    sell to eligible countries at the long-term
    price, contract allows sponsor to acquire right
    to produce
  • Supplier(s) turn over IP to the sponsor but
    supplier may not have the right to sublicense all
    the IP
  • Conflicts because supplier retains IP rights to
    non-eligible markets
  • Sponsor has difficulties acquiring know how and
    production
  • Threat undermines incentives to invest in vaccine
    RD
  • Threat undermines incentives to invest in vaccine
    delivery systems
  • Severe supply shortages and damaging access
    delays
  • Reputational damage issues for supplier and
    sponsor(s)
  • Not credible way to discipline firms.

49
What if firms wont/cant supply? 2
  • Contract term sheets say other penalties such
    as liquidated damages provisions imposed on
    supplier
  • Contract leaves details blank
  • Threat feeds back to weaken ex ante incentives to
    invest in RD in the first place (especially if
    provisions are so vague)
  • Threat can create perverse incentive not to
    supply eligible market in the first place or
    delay supplying eligible market
  • HIV vaccine in particular, given richer
    non-eligible markets and the option value of the
    APC given the different HIV clades.
  • Threat weakens incentive to invest in vaccine
    delivery systems
  • Not credible way to discipline firms.
  • Contract term sheets leave blank those sections
    specifying remedies in the event of a breach.

50
What if firms wont/cant supply? 3
  • IP and know-how barriers have been principal
    causes of delays in achieving flexible,
    cost-effective manufacturing and quick access to
    vaccines for the poor in the past.
  • Now control of IP and know-how part of a threat
    mechanism to drive the contracts!
  • If the threats do not work, how do production
    costs get low enough to supply the ex post
    market?
  • Lack of competition
  • Weakened price signals due to the presence of the
    APC
  • Lack of access to technology
  • Insufficient pressures to lower production costs
  • This is all contrary to, e.g., the Hepatitis B
    case, and to application of APC-type arrangements
    to current late-stage vaccines.

51
What if firms wont/cant supply? 4
  • Legal advisors inform this author that threats in
    contracts at 20 year horizons are not used in
    practice.
  • Long-term price and sustainable production
    capacity for eligible countries thereby
    unresolved in MM report.
  • Excessive emphasis on getting the 3bn to the
    supplier(s) of the first 200m or so eligible
    treatments, and insufficient attention to
    follow-on suppliers and the post-200m treatments.
  • A mechanism that relies on this presumption in
    order for it to work should be treated with a
    great deal of caution, indeed skepticism
    especially when, after 8 years since the idea
    first surfaced, the contract writers havent a
    clue how to do it.
  • Vaccine developers facing many risks that a
    viable mechanism should seek to remove from them.

52
Follow-on innovation 1
  • Advance purchase commitments may also stifle
    incremental innovation. Because they create a
    winner takes all solution, it would be
    difficult for incremental, follow-on competitors
    to emerge, thus dulling the benefits of
    competition on cost and improvements. The
    innovation that wins will crowd out competing
    inventions because it is being given away free by
    the public sector. This crowding out effect
    means that no improvements will be made to the
    winning formulation, and this may have negative
    consequences for resistance and effectiveness in
    subpopulations. International Policy Network
    Incentivising research and development for the
    diseases of poverty, 2005 p15.

53
Follow-on innovation 2
  • "It is difficult to get the right quality, in
    particular to reward follow-on products that
    offer higher quality. Our view is that it should
    be possible to set an effective quality
    threshold, and that the terms of the APC must
    allow for superior quality follow-on products to
    be used(However) there may not be enough money
    left in the initial APC to reward the RD
    involved in developing some of the superior
    follow-on products. This is quite possible, as
    the commitment is only designed to generate at
    least one product that meets the quality
    threshold. Clearly a view would have to be taken
    by the donors as to whether they wished to
    finance follow-on products with additional money.
    This would be a separate investment decision from
    the original APC." Towse, A. and Kettler, H, A
    Review of IP and Non-IP Incentives for RD for
    Diseases of Poverty.What Type of Innovation is
    Required and How Can We Incentivise the Private
    Sector to Deliver It? April 2005, p87.

54
Follow-on innovation 3
  • However, so as not to harm investor incentives,
    this additional money for follow-on products
    should be credibly promised in advance if not
    part of the original APC but that makes this
    additional money, by default, part of an
    original APC-type arrangement!
  • Efficient incentives require each generation of
    products to cover its expected RD costs. How
    achieved?
  • MM removes Quantity guarantee to (supposedly)
    remove the risk that the sponsor will end up
    funding a non-used product, and to give
    incentives for follow-on products.
  • Multidimensional quality problem a quality
    surface over vaccines, over time. Set terms
    wrong and disincentivize (dynamic) investment.
    Expectations are everything to investors.

55
Follow-on innovation 4
  • MM suggests potentially very complicated rules
    about qualities of acceptable vaccines, and
    variation in allocations and prices of vaccine
    purchases across multiple developers and
    purchasers, and over time
  • But no practical details of how this is done
  • Hard to visualize that policy makers could derive
    the optimal way to hold back on early products
    so as to leave funds for later products.
  • Hugely aggravated by the fact that the likely
    quality improvements, science, and costs are all
    highly uncertain.
  • Also no ex ante grasp of the potential timing of
    anything, or characteristics of firms such as
    access to finance, risk tolerance, etc.
  • On average, achieving quality is more
    expensive.
  • Will investors expect the distribution of the
    subsidy to be efficient?

56
Follow-on innovation 5
  • Constant danger of poor vaccines driving out
    better vaccines (aggravated if the overall fund
    is set too low to start with).
  • Need for follow-on instruments (Towse and
    Kettler, ibid.) but these need to be fully
    articulated and credibly promised in advance if
    investors are not to be harmed.
  • Dangers that fund becomes unbounded at top, yet
    still highly uncertain killing dynamic
    incentives.
  • Original (Kremer) model is static and ignores
    these issues.
  • In particular it presumes one vaccine target.
  • Recently, these dynamics are simply presumed
    perfectly performed by the committee
  • In truth the committee would fall massively short
    and investor and researcher expectations would
    respond accordingly.

57
Follow-on innovation 6
  • Recent malaria case so far no attention at all
    to dynamic incentives in CGD and UK policy
    announcements.
  • End up with a committee with discretion, risk to
    investors, higher risk premia, more pressure to
    go for lower quality, and rent seeking behaviour
    of big players?
  • Follow-on products also covers cases of
    complete vaccine replacement.
  • Incentives to actually carry out this
    replacement?
  • Incentives to expediently create capacity when
    vaccines are replaced?
  • Replacement is only statistical. How is this
    handled in size and distribution rules of APC?
  • All the time there is the need for developing
    country trust of vaccine products and of ethical
    trials.

58
Follow-on problems especially severe for HIV,
malaria and TB
  • An Arms war between virus and drugs/vaccines.
  • First vaccines not necessarily the best
  • More so if only therapeutic and not preventative.
  • Expectations about payments to the first must not
    stifle incentives for later needed vaccines.
  • Expectations about payments to non-composite
    vaccines must not stifle incentives for composite
    vaccines
  • HIV vaccines coordination, information sharing,
    and timing worries.
  • Expectations about payments for therapeutic
    vaccines
  • Needing monitoring and even more long-term
    follow-on vaccines.
  • Worries that better vaccines arrive after
    subsidies are gone.
  • Second-generation vaccine costs even harder to
    work out in advance than first-generation costs.
  • It is all about INVESTOR EXPECTATIONS.

59
The paradox of market risk 1
  • For most late-stage and underused vaccines the
    objective of purchase commitments is to remove
    market risk.
  • Early-stage vaccine APCs (as currently designed)
    put market risk back on to vaccine developers
    (supposedly) to, ex post, drive the quality
    rules and ex ante effort incentives. BUT
  • These are resource-poor markets
  • Most buyers are relatively uninformed (about
    current vaccines never mind about expected future
    vaccines)
  • There are no marketing budgets
  • Vaccine usage needs a good distribution system,
    with such systems generally not under the control
    of vaccine companies
  • There are heavy knock-on costs to purchase
    decisions
  • There are multiple organizational problems

60
The paradox of market risk 2
  • There is a severe lack of qualified personnel on
    the ground
  • There are multiple political interests
  • There are cultural barriers
  • There are plenty of ways to encourage
    decision-makers to take one firms product over
    another firms product (even more so if the
    other firms product does not exist yet)
  • There are strong self-fulfilling pressures in
    the co-payment mechanism driving towards
    lower-quality outcomes
  • This, ex ante, feeds investor expectations and
    RD incentives towards the low-quality
    outcomes.
  • Why put all these risks back on to vaccine
    developers in order to try get this mechanism to
    work for early-stage vaccines and to try to
    create follow-on incentives?
  • Less of an issue if system collapses down to
    just the one vaccine but that, supposedly, was
    not the point.

61
The paradox of market risk 3
  • Maybe intention is that mechanism collapses down
    to a limited number of developers?
  • In case-studies, production scale and competition
    were key to low-cost vaccine production.
  • No sense using (expected) restrictions and
    holding back of sales of a single supplier to
    discipline quality.
  • Why inflict uncertainty on investors seeking to
    scale up manufacturing capacity?
  • It is dynamically inconsistent anyway hard to
    hold back on a bird-in-the-hand vaccine to
    supposedly discipline quality and to leave
    funds for later vaccines.
  • Leads to further pressure to lower quality with
    risk to quality investors.
  • More likely just lots of uncertainty, higher
    capital costs, and fewer developers in the end
    game.

62
This paradox undermines RD incentives
  • Hard to see how any quality control over the
    whole development process could be done in the
    end-game in this way without conflicting with the
    need to get the manufacturing costs low.
  • RESULT A mechanism that disciplines quality en
    route is better able to achieve larger capacity,
    multiple suppliers, and low prices, than is the
    mechanism that disciplines quality via holding
    back in the end market. A FUNDAMENTAL CONFLICT.
  • Paradoxically, undermines investors who will not
    believe that manufacturing costs will be pushed
    low enough ex post to make the whole investment
    exercise worthwhile ex ante (see forthcoming
    slide for more on this).

63
Incentives to block second generation products
  • Unlike patents, the first to market is likely to
    get all the subsidy if it can hold off
    follow-on vaccines just long enough. Even
    better if it can create the reputation for this
    it becomes self-fulfilling and the firm gets the
    subsidy quicker (if there is discretion over how
    to split the subsidy).
  • With standard patent-based systems and marketing,
    firms can more easily agree to split the market,
    so there is incentive to share/license/split the
    higher price for the better product.
  • This has all gone.
  • This gives strong incentives for the
    first-generation developers to block (advertently
    or inadvertently) second generation vaccines (via
    not sharing IP, know-how, etc.).

64
The sums dont add up either
  • Pricing structure can be designed to provide
    substantial insurance against demand risk for
    prospective vaccine developers so as to yield a
    net present value of revenue comparable to
    commercial products even under pessimistic uptake
    scenarios, MM March 2005 p50 and p114, emphasis
    added
  • Indicates the complicated tradeoff that needs to
    take place, not that it would take place or ever
    could take place (it could not, because of the
    intractable information problems needed to make
    it work)
  • Commercial return means ex ante commercial
    return. What happens when that is gone?
  • No way to know how to set any of this many years
    in advance.
  • In reality, according to recent announcements,
    seems little intention to use any of these
    dynamic rules anyway.

65
Two-stage game problems
  • Always better to compete for contract before
    sinking costs.
  • Award after costs are sunk runs the risk of
    forcing firms to compete twice
  • RD stage
  • Market stage.
  • Bygones are bygonesAfter costs are sunk,
    always worth spending up to the value of the
    contract in rent-seeking behavior to win the
    contract.
  • In such situations, firms expect to face a
    negative rate of return from the overall project.
  • CONSEQUENCE The incumbent firm signals/behaves
    in ways to increase the expected risk of later
    firms. No second firm bothers to enter whatever
    the size of the commitment. Competition is
    stifled.

66
Avoiding two-stage game problems
  • Must fix terms at the start to make it clear that
    no amount of lobbying/spending at the second
    stage will change the payouts.
  • BUT
  • Contradicts the need for discretion to change
    terms
  • Becomes mechanistic based on expectations at the
    very start
  • E.g. HIV science that is 10-20 years out of date!
  • Real problems if a market test is used since
    firms can try to influence purchase decisions
    (illegal kickbacks, bundling to hide discounts.
    There are sanctions against the former if
    detected. Hard to detect the latter and fewer
    sanctions)
  • Biased against small biotechs (cant bundle and
    cant hide other subsidies), not-for-profits (who
    may not be allowed to behave in these ways), and
    emerging developers. Again, expectations of this
    will disadvantage the latter groups when trying
    to acquire finance for RD.

67
Ex ante versus ex post information problems an
unhelpful caricature
  • Sponsors of APCs said to need little knowledge
    about the likely success of particular
    approaches.
  • But, they do need a huge amount of qualitative
    and quantitative information about overall set of
    potential scientific, epidemiological, expected
    research and manufacturing costs, existing
    market possibilities, etc. well in advance of
    product development in order to get the terms
    vaguely efficient.
  • To be credible and to minimise the risks to
    firms, firms need to trust that policy-makers
    have this ex ante information. Otherwise, lots of
    discretion later and risk.
  • Mechanism cannot claim it solves information
    difficulties it has ruled out at the start.

68
Crowding out weakens pull 1
  • The proposal is that private investment would
    underpin RD by private firms Barder, O., CIPIH
    Forum, 19 November 2004.
  • Has to be additional incentive
  • Additional to current RD
  • Additional to current market.
  • Has to be believed that it will be additional.
  • This is a big challenge.
  • Easy to achieve additionality for underused
    vaccines
  • It is a total non-issue.
  • More difficult to achieve for late-stage vaccines
    though still possible
  • Run a competitive tender (with more access to IP)
    and use known scientific information, etc.

69
Crowding out weakens pull 2
  • Extremely difficult to achieve for early-stage
    vaccines.
  • Referring to HIV/AIDS, perinatal conditions,
    maternal conditions, childhood diseases, malaria,
    and tuberculosis
  • All of these are health problems in the first
    world too, and, ignoring the special case of
    mutant strains, there are substantial incentives
    for the development of effective therapies.
    Malaria is perhaps the principal exception, but
    there is a lot of work on it currently. To be
    sure, some diseases occur primarily in the third
    world, but the magnitude of the problem that is
    uniquely without solution ought to be brought
    into sharper perspective. F.M. Scherer, CIPIH
    May 2005. Emphasis added.
  • Pull payment to any firm would need to be reduced
    by many times the push payments it had ever
    received to achieve a level playing field between
    firms (unless unequal access to push efforts can
    be made to be part of the efficient solution).

70
Crowding out weakens pull 3
  • For scientific areas with a complicated interplay
    of push and pull and a large push element, there
    is great risk that the pull-motivated will lose
    out to the push-motivated and to those not
    relying on an APC for their funding
  • Allowing heavily push-motivated and
    PPP/philanthropic-financed players to have access
    to the fund, effectively weakens the expected
    value of the fund to the APC players.
  • SIMPLE EXAMPLE
  • 10 firms working equally hard on HIV vaccines,
    70 capital costs, no splitting of 6.25bn APC
    fund
  • Winning firm has 50 subsidies, grant support,
    non-private funding, etc.
  • Winning firm should be denied just over 3bn of
    the fund
  • 3bn left in the pot for competing and
    follow-on vaccines
  • But every 1m of hiding, worth nearly 17m to
    the firm.

71
Crowding out weakens pull 4
  • Needs a great deal of monitoring. Paradoxical
    given that those advocating the program often
    highlight the opposite.
  • Need for high-quality historical evidence (20-30
    years).
  • Need for committees, discretion, treaties?
  • Impossible to correctly price streams of other
    payments (e.g. appropriate capital costs?).
  • Repayment side-contracts that may not unfold
    for ten or twenty or more years.
  • The mechanism claims that to work out an optimal
    strategy, every firm needs to know how much
    privately-funded activity is taking place. How is
    this achievedif what is going on is so opaque?
  • Private firms need to trust that push is being
    efficiently handled.

72
Crowding out weakens pull 5
  • Favors large pharma players for early-stage
    vaccines
  • Smaller firms, biotechs, not-for-profit firms,
    etc. have many fewer ways to hide research
    supports (if they can get them)
  • Many biotechs work on one area only their
    funding flows are less opaque than large pharma
    players
  • Easier for large pharma to avoid monitoring
    generally.
  • Standard procurement contracts capable of paying
    only for additional private funds to finish a
    project
  • Competitive tender separates out the push from
    the pull funding.
  • Here, Framework Agreement is the tender.
  • Here, highly complicated side device has to be
    appended to the tender to achieve a standard
    property.

73
Crowding out weakens pull 6
  • Near-scratch versus near-market
  • APC (if not appropriately adjusted)
    disproportionately benefits those nearer to
    market, even if not the ultimately best
    vaccine
  • Disincentivizes near-scratch developers
  • This reduces the average expected quality of
    vaccines.
  • PPP funding
  • How exactly do PPP activities complement and
    not conflict with APC-based private activities?
  • Should an MVI- or IAVI-funded vaccine be denied
    APC funds?
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com