Lecture 18: Testing CAPM - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 32
About This Presentation
Title:

Lecture 18: Testing CAPM

Description:

Fama-MacBeth (1973) Approach. L18: CAPM. 2. Review of CAPM ... MacBeth: use a procedure that is now known as the 'Fama-MacBeth ... Fama and MacBeth (1973) ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:1262
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 33
Provided by: ton48
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Lecture 18: Testing CAPM


1
Lecture 18 Testing CAPM
  • The following topics will be covered
  • Time Series Tests
  • Sharpe (1964)/Litner (1965) version
  • Black (1972) version
  • Cross Sectional Tests
  • Fama-MacBeth (1973) Approach

2
Review of CAPM
  • Let there be N risky assets with mean µ and
    variance ?

3
Review of CAPM
  • This is the case without risk free asset
  • We have
  • And
  • µop is the return of the zero beta portfolio
  • This is the Black version of CAPM

4
Review of CAPM
5
Review of CAPM
6
Test of Sharpe-Lintner CAMP
7
Time-Series Tests Maximum Likelihood Approach
  • There are N assets and hence, N equations.
  • For each equation, we can run OLS and obtain
    estimates of ?i and ?i, I 1,,N.
  • We could also estimate the equations jointly.
  • Is there any advantage to doing this, that is,
    run the seemingly unrelated regression on the
    system?
  • As it turns out, joint estimation is useless if
    we only need estimates for ?s and ?s.
  • However, for our joint test, its not useless.
    We need the covariance matrix for our joint test.

8
The Likelihood Function
  • We will assume that the distribution for excess
    returns are jointly normal. This is critical for
    the maximum likelihood approach. However, if we
    use Quasi ML, or GMM, we do not need normality
    assumption.
  • Given joint normality of excess returns, the
    likelihood function for the cross-section of
    excess returns in a single period is

9
The Likelihood Function
  • With T i.i.d. (over time) observations, the
    likelihood function is

10
MLE Estimates of Parameters
  • Why do it this way? Because if you know the
    distribution, MLEs are
  • Consistent
  • Asymptotically efficient
  • Asymptotically normal
  • The log of the joint pdf viewed as a function of
    the unkown parameters, ?, ?, and ?.

11
First Order Conditions
  • The ML parameter estimates maximize L. To find
    the estimators, set the FOCs to zero
  • There are N of these derivataives one for each
    ?i.
  • There are N of these as well, one for each ?i.
    Finally,

12
Solution
  • These are just OLS parameters for ?, and ?.

13
Distributions of the Point Estimates
  • The distributions of the MLEs conditional on the
    excess return of the market follows from the
    assumed joint normality of the excess returns and
    the i.i.d. assumption.
  • The variances and covariances of the estimators
    can be derived using the Fisher Information
    Matrix.
  • The information matrix is minus the matrix of
    second partials of the log-likelihood function
    with respect to the parameter vector.
  • evaluated at the point estimates.

14
Asymptotic Properties of Estimators
  • The estimators are consistent and have the
    distributions
  • WN(T-2, ?) indicates that the NxN covariance
    matrix T? has a Wishart distribution with T-2
    degrees of freedom, a multivariate generalization
    of the chi-squared distribution.
  • Note that is independent of both

15
The Test Statistic
  • We estimated the unconstrained market model to
    obtain the MLEs.
  • Now, we impose the CAPM restrictions.
  • If the CAPM is true, under the null
  • H0 ? 0
  • and under the alternative
  • HA ? ? 0
  • From your previous econometrics course, you
    probably remember that there are three ways of
    testing this.
  • If we only estimate the unconstrained model, we
    can the Wald test.
  • We will also consider likelihood ratio and
    Lagrangian multiplier tests.

16
The Wald Test
  • A straightforward application (see Greene or
    earlier notes).
  • which equals
  • where weve substituted in for
  • Under the null, J0?2(N).
  • Note that ? is unknown.
  • Substitute a consistent estimate of it into the
    statistic and then under the null the
    distribution is asymptotically chi-squared.
  • The MLE of ? is a consistent estimator.

17
We Can Do Better
  • The Wald test is an asymptotic test.
  • We, however, know the finite sample distribution.
  • We can use this to do the Gibbons Ross and Shaken
    (1989) test.
  • To do so, we will need the following theorem from
    Muirhead (1983).
  • Theorem Let the m-vector x be distributed
    N(0,?), let the (mxm) matrix A be distributed
    Wm(n,?) with n?m, and let x and A be independent.
    Then

18
GRS Statistic
  • Let
  • Applying the theorem,
  • Under the null, J1 F(N,T-N-1).
  • We can construct J1 (and J0) using only the
    estimators from the unconstrained model.

19
An Interpretation of J1
  • GRS show that
  • q is the ex-post tangency portfolio constructed
    from the N assets plus the market portfolio.
  • The portfolio with the maximum (squared) Sharpe
    ratio must be the tangency portfolio.
  • When the ex-post q is m, J1 0.
  • As ms squared SR decreases, J1 increases
    evidence against the efficiency of m.

20
The Likelihood Ratio Test
  • For the LR test, we must also estimate the
    constrained model, which is the S-L CAPM (?0).
  • FOCs

21
The Constrained Estimators
  • The estimators are consistent and have the
    following distributions (why T-1?)

22
The LR Test
  • We know from econometrics (CLM p194) that
  • This test is based on the fact that 2 times the
    log of the likelihood ratio is asymptotically
    ?2 with d.f. equal to the number of restrictions
    under the null.
  • The test statistic is
  • CLM (p195) show that there is a monotonic
    relationship between J1 and J2
  • Therefore we can derive finite sample
    distribution for J2 based on the finite sample
    distribution of J1

23
Jobson and Korkie (1982) Adjustment
  • which is also asymptotically distributed as a
  • Why do we need different statistics?
  • Because although their asymptotic properties are
    similar, they may have different small-sample
    properties.

24
Black version of CAMP
25
Testable Implication
  • This is a nonlinear constraint. It may looks more
    complicated. But if you remember from your
    econometrics course, all three statsistics (Wald,
    Likelihood Ratio, Lagrangian Multiplier) can
    easily test nonlinear restrictions.
  • CLM construct test statistics J4, J5, and J6 to
    test the Black CAPM. See CLM p199-203.

26
Size and Power
  • They also use simulations to compare small sample
    properties of all the statistics (Section 5.4 and
    5.5 )
  • Size simulation simulate under the null, and
    compare the rejection rates under simulation with
    the theoretical rejection rates
  • Power simulation simulate under the alternative,
    and see if rejection rate is high enough.

27
Further Issues
  • What if assets returns are not normal?
  • One alternative approach is to use quasi-maximum
    likelihood. Under certain regularity conditions
    you can estimate the model as if the returns were
    normally distributed, and the Wald, Likelihood
    ratio, and Lagrangian multiplier tests are still
    valid (after adjusting for the covariance matrix
    for the errors).
  • However, small sample properties of QMLE are of
    serious concern.
  • Another alternative is to use GMM, which only
    rely on a few momentum conditions.

28
Cross-sectional Test
  • Consider the cross-sectional model (Security
    Market Line)
  • E(Ri) Rf ßi (E(Rm) Rf )
  • or, replacing expected returns with average
    returns,
  • ave(Ri) Rf ßi (E(Rm) Rf ) ei
  • ? ave(Ri) a ? ßi ei
  • Sharpe-Lintner CAPM says that in the above
    cross-sectional regression, a should equal Rf and
    ? should equal E(Rm) Rf .
  • To perform the above regression, we use ßi as a
    regressor. However, ßi is not directly observed.
    We can estimate ßi using a market model (using
    time series observations) for each stock. But if
    we use the estimated ßi , there is an
    error-in-variable problem for the above
    regression.
  • Whats the consequence of error-in-variable
    problem?
  • a upward biased and ? downward biased

29
Issues with Cross-sectional Tests
  • To alleviate the error-in-variable problem, BJS
    and FM group stocks into equally weighted
    portfolios (betas of portfolios are more
    accurate)
  • But an arbitrarily formed portfolio tends to have
    beta 1.
  • The maximize the power of test, group stocks into
    portfolios based on stocks betas.
  • Unsolved problems errors ei are correlated
    across stocks. This causes problems for
    estimating standard deviations of coefficient
    estimates.
  • Fama and MacBeth use a procedure that is now
    known as the Fama-MacBeth regression

30
Fama and MacBeth (1973)
  • Perform the cross-sectional regression in each
    month, to obtain rolling estimates for a and ?.
    Call them at and ?t . Then, calculate the time
    series means and time series t-stats for at and
    ?t .
  • Test
  • ave(at ) ave(Rf) and ave(?t ) gt0
  • t-stat ave(?t)/std(?t)sqrt(T)
  • Discussion under what assumptions is this t test
    valid and why?
  • They also perform the test using an extended
    model
  • Ri ?0 ?1 ßi ?2 ßi2 ?3 si2 ei
  • and test ave(?2) ave(?3) 0

31
Results from Cross-sectional Tests
  • Estimated a seems too high, relative to the
    average riskfree rate.
  • Estimated ? too low, relative to the average
    market risk premium.
  • Black version of CAPM seems more consistent with
    the data.
  • Other variables, such as squared beta and the
    variance of idiosyncratic component of returns,
    do not have marginal power to explain average
    returns.
  • In other words, C1 and C2 seem to hold C3 is
    rejected.

32
Exercises
  • CLM
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com