A portfoli - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 110
About This Presentation
Title:

A portfoli

Description:

It is dangerous to invest all our money into a single asset. ... to be positive, the instability will manifest itself by more and more weights ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:21
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 111
Provided by: col69
Category:
Tags: best | invest | manifest | money | portfoli | to | way

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: A portfoli


1
A portfolió-választási feladat instabilitása
  • Kondor Imre
  • Collegium Budapest és ELTE
  • Eloadás az MTA Közgazdaságtudományi
    Intézetében
  • Budapest, 2006 március 2

2
Contents
  • The subject of the talk lies at the crossroads
    of finance, statistical physics and computer
    science
  • I. The investment problem portfolios, rational
    portfolio selection, risk measures, the
    problem of estimation error (noise), noise
    sensitivity of risk measures
  • II. A wider context algorithms, computational
    complexity, critical phenomena, estimation error
    as a critical phenomenon

3
Contents
  • The subject of the talk lies at the crossroads
    of finance, statistical physics and computer
    science
  • I. The investment problem portfolios, rational
    portfolio selection, risk measures, the
    problem of estimation error (noise), noise
    sensitivity of risk measures
  • II. A wider context algorithms, computational
    complexity, critical phenomena, estimation error
    as a critical phenomenon

4
Contents
  • The subject of the talk lies at the crossroads
    of finance, statistical physics and computer
    science
  • I. The investment problem portfolios, rational
    portfolio selection, risk measures, the
    problem of estimation error (noise), noise
    sensitivity of risk measures
  • II. A wider context algorithms, computational
    complexity, critical phenomena, estimation error
    as a critical phenomenon

5
A disclaimer
  • This talk is not about
  • human nature
  • utility functions
  • the structure of markets
  • the nature of data
  • bounded rationality.
  • It is about the purely technical question of risk
    measures as they appear in practice, their noise
    sensitivity and the limitations this imposes upon
    rational decision making.

6
Coworkers
  • Szilárd Pafka (ELTE PhD student ? CIB Bank,
    ?Paycom.net, California)
  • Gábor Nagy (Debrecen University PhD student and
    CIB Bank, Budapest)
  • Richárd Karádi (Technical University MSc student
    ?ProcterGamble)
  • Nándor Gulyás (ELTE PhD student ? Budapest Bank
    ?Lombard Leasing ?private enterpreneur)
  • István Varga-Haszonits (ELTE PhD student
    ?Morgan-Stanley)

7
A portfolio
  • is a combination of assets or investment
    instruments (shares, bonds, foreign exchange,
    precious metals, commodities, artworks, property,
    etc.).
  • In this talk I will focus on equity portfolios.
  • More generally, the various business lines of a
    big firm, or even the economy as a whole, can
    also be regarded as a portfolio.

8
A portfolio
  • is a combination of assets or investment
    instruments (shares, bonds, foreign exchange,
    precious metals, commodities, artworks, property,
    etc.).
  • In this talk I will focus on equity portfolios.
  • More generally, the various business lines of a
    big firm, or even the economy as a whole, can
    also be regarded as a portfolio.

9
A portfolio
  • is a combination of assets or investment
    instruments (shares, bonds, foreign exchange,
    precious metals, commodities, artworks, property,
    etc.).
  • In this talk I will focus on equity portfolios.
  • More generally, the various business lines of a
    big firm, or even the economy as a whole, can
    also be regarded as a portfolio.

10
Rational portfolio selection
  • The value of assets fluctuates.
  • It is dangerous to invest all our money into a
    single asset.
  • Investment should be diversified, distributed
    among the various assets.
  • More risky assets tend to yield higher return.
  • Some assets tend to fluctuate together, some
    others in an opposite way.
  • Rational portfolio selection seeks a tradeoff
    between risk and reward.

11
(No Transcript)
12
Relative price change (return)
13
(No Transcript)
14
(No Transcript)
15
Rational portfolio selection
  • The value of assets fluctuates.
  • It is dangerous to invest all our money into a
    single asset.
  • Investment should be diversified, distributed
    among the various assets.
  • More risky assets tend to yield higher return.
  • Some assets tend to fluctuate together, some
    others in an opposite way.
  • Rational portfolio selection seeks a tradeoff
    between risk and reward.

16
Rational portfolio selection
  • The value of assets fluctuates.
  • It is dangerous to invest all our money into a
    single asset.
  • Investment should be diversified, distributed
    among the various assets.
  • More risky assets tend to yield higher return.
  • Some assets tend to fluctuate together, some
    others in an opposite way.
  • Rational portfolio selection seeks a tradeoff
    between risk and reward.

17
Rational portfolio selection
  • The value of assets fluctuates.
  • It is dangerous to invest all our money into a
    single asset.
  • Investment should be diversified, distributed
    among the various assets.
  • More risky assets tend to yield higher return.
  • Some assets tend to fluctuate together, some
    others in an opposite way.
  • Rational portfolio selection seeks a tradeoff
    between risk and reward.

18
(No Transcript)
19
(No Transcript)
20
(No Transcript)
21
(No Transcript)
22
(No Transcript)
23
(No Transcript)
24
Mean 0.0017 StdDev 0.016
25
Mean 0.00028 StdDev 0.0038
26
Rational portfolio selection
  • The value of assets fluctuates.
  • It is dangerous to invest all our money into a
    single asset.
  • Investment should be diversified, distributed
    among the various assets.
  • More risky assets tend to yield higher return.
  • Some assets tend to fluctuate together, some
    others in an opposite way.
  • Rational portfolio selection seeks a tradeoff
    between risk and reward.

27
(No Transcript)
28
(No Transcript)
29
Rational portfolio selection
  • The value of assets fluctuates.
  • It is dangerous to invest all our money into a
    single asset.
  • Investment should be diversified, distributed
    among the various assets.
  • More risky assets tend to yield higher return.
  • Some assets tend to fluctuate together, some
    others in an opposite way.
  • Rational portfolio selection seeks a tradeoff
    between risk and reward.

30
Risk and reward
  • Financial reward can be measured in terms of the
    return (relative gain)
  • The characterization of risk is more controversial

31
Risk measures
  • A risk measure is a quantitative characterization
    of our intuitive concept of risk (fear of loss).
  • Risk is related to the stochastic nature of
    returns. Mathematically, it is (or should be) a
    convex functional of the pdf of returns.
  • The appropriate choice may depend on the nature
    of data (e.g. on their asymptotics) and on the
    context (investment, risk management,
    benchmarking, tracking, regulation, capital
    allocation)

32
Risk measures
  • A risk measure is a quantitative characterization
    of our intuitive concept of risk (fear of loss).
  • Risk is related to the stochastic nature of
    returns. Mathematically, it is (or should be) a
    convex functional of the pdf of returns.
  • The appropriate choice may depend on the nature
    of data (e.g. on their asymptotics) and on the
    context (investment, risk management,
    benchmarking, tracking, regulation, capital
    allocation)

33
Risk measures
  • A risk measure is a quantitative characterization
    of our intuitive concept of risk (fear of loss).
  • Risk is related to the stochastic nature of
    returns. Mathematically, it is (or should be) a
    convex functional of the pdf of returns.
  • The appropriate choice may depend on the nature
    of data (e.g. on their asymptotics) and on the
    context (investment, risk management,
    benchmarking, tracking, regulation, capital
    allocation)

34
The most obvious choice for a risk measure
Variance
  • Variance is the average quadratic deviation from
    the average a time honoured statistical tool
  • Its use assumes that the probability distribution
    of the returns is sufficiently concentrated
    around the average, that there are no large
    fluctuations
  • This is true in several instances, but we often
    encounter fat tails, huge deviations with a
    non-negligible probability (e.g. the Black
    Monday).

35
The most obvious choice for a risk measure
Variance
  • Variance is the average quadratic deviation from
    the average a time honoured statistical tool
  • Its use assumes that the probability distribution
    of the returns is sufficiently concentrated
    around the average, that there are no large
    fluctuations
  • This is true in several instances, but we often
    encounter fat tails, huge deviations with a
    non-negligible probability (e.g. the Black
    Monday).

36
The most obvious choice for a risk measure
Variance
  • Variance is the average quadratic deviation from
    the average a time honoured statistical tool
  • Its use assumes that the probability distribution
    of the returns is sufficiently concentrated
    around the average, that there are no large
    fluctuations
  • This is true in several instances, but we often
    encounter fat tails, huge deviations with a
    non-negligible probability (e.g. the Black
    Monday).

37
Alternative risk measures
  • There are several alternative risk measures in
    use in the academic literature, practice, and
    regulation
  • Value at risk (VaR) the best among the p
    worst losses (not convex, punishes
    diversification)
  • Mean absolute deviation (MAD) Algorithmics
  • Coherent risk measures (promoted by academics)
  • Expected shortfall (ES) average loss beyond a
    high threshold
  • Maximal loss (ML) the single worst case

38
Alternative risk measures
  • There are several alternative risk measures in
    use in the academic literature, practice, and
    regulation
  • Value at risk (VaR) the best among the p
    worst losses (not convex, punishes
    diversification)
  • Mean absolute deviation (MAD) Algorithmics
  • Coherent risk measures (promoted by academics)
  • Expected shortfall (ES) average loss beyond a
    high threshold
  • Maximal loss (ML) the single worst case

39
Alternative risk measures
  • There are several alternative risk measures in
    use in the academic literature, practice, and
    regulation
  • Value at risk (VaR) the best among the p
    worst losses (not convex, punishes
    diversification)
  • Mean absolute deviation (MAD) Algorithmics
  • Coherent risk measures (promoted by academics)
  • Expected shortfall (ES) average loss beyond a
    high threshold
  • Maximal loss (ML) the single worst case

40
Alternative risk measures
  • There are several alternative risk measures in
    use in the academic literature, practice, and
    regulation
  • Value at risk (VaR) the best among the p
    worst losses (not convex, punishes
    diversification)
  • Mean absolute deviation (MAD) Algorithmics
  • Coherent risk measures (promoted by academics)
  • Expected shortfall (ES) average loss beyond a
    high threshold
  • Maximal loss (ML) the single worst case

41
The variance of a portfolio
  • - a quadratic form of the weights. The
    coefficients of this form are the elements of the
    covariance matrix that measures the co-movements
    between the various assets.

42
Portfolios
  • A portfolio is a linear combination (a weighted
    average) of assets, with a set of weights wi that
    add up to unity (the budget constraint).
  • The weights are not necessarily positive short
    selling
  • The legal status of short selling
  • Leverage
  • The fact that the weights can be negative means
    that the region over which we are trying to
    determine the optimal portfolio is not bounded

43
Portfolios
  • A portfolio is a linear combination (a weighted
    average) of assets, with a set of weights wi that
    add up to unity (the budget constraint).
  • The weights are not necessarily positive short
    selling
  • The legal status of short selling
  • Leverage
  • The fact that the weights can be negative means
    that the region over which we are trying to
    determine the optimal portfolio is not bounded

44
Portfolios
  • A portfolio is a linear combination (a weighted
    average) of assets, with a set of weights wi that
    add up to unity (the budget constraint).
  • The weights are not necessarily positive short
    selling
  • The legal status of short selling
  • Leverage
  • The fact that the weights can be negative means
    that the region over which we are trying to
    determine the optimal portfolio is not bounded

45
Portfolios
  • A portfolio is a linear combination (a weighted
    average) of assets, with a set of weights wi that
    add up to unity (the budget constraint).
  • The weights are not necessarily positive short
    selling
  • The legal status of short selling
  • Leverage
  • The fact that the weights can be negative means
    that the region over which we are trying to
    determine the optimal portfolio is not bounded

46
Portfolios
  • A portfolio is a linear combination (a weighted
    average) of assets, with a set of weights wi that
    add up to unity (the budget constraint).
  • The weights are not necessarily positive short
    selling
  • The legal status of short selling
  • Leverage
  • The fact that the weights can be negative means
    that the region over which we are trying to
    determine the optimal portfolio is not bounded

47
Markowitz portfolio selection theory
  • Rational portfolio selection realizes the
    tradeoff between risk and reward by minimizing
    the risk functional over the weights, given the
    expected return, the budget constraint, and
    possibly other costraints.

48
Ambiguity of the objective function
  • The non-uniqueness of risk measures is a serious
    problem (most banks use internal models different
    from what they use for regulatory reporting).
    What do we want to optimize?
  • The most popular risk measure, also deeply
    embedded in regulation, is VaR, which is
    inconsistent
  • The lack of a universally agreed objective
    function is not unique to finance
  • Single period vs. multiperiod optimization

49
Ambiguity of the objective function
  • The non-uniqueness of risk measures is a serious
    problem (most banks use internal models different
    from what they use for regulatory reporting).
    What do we want to optimize?
  • The most popular risk measure, also deeply
    embedded in regulation, is VaR, which is
    inconsistent
  • The lack of a universally agreed objective
    function is not unique to finance
  • Single period vs. multiperiod optimization

50
Ambiguity of the objective function
  • The non-uniqueness of risk measures is a serious
    problem (most banks use internal models different
    from what they use for regulatory reporting).
    What do we want to optimize?
  • The most popular risk measure, also deeply
    embedded in regulation, is VaR, which is
    inconsistent
  • The lack of a universally agreed objective
    function is not unique to finance
  • Single period vs. multiperiod optimization

51
Ambiguity of the objective function
  • The non-uniqueness of risk measures is a serious
    problem (most banks use internal models different
    from what they use for regulatory reporting).
    What do we want to optimize?
  • The most popular risk measure, also deeply
    embedded in regulation, is VaR, which is
    inconsistent
  • The lack of a universally agreed objective
    function is not unique to finance
  • Single period vs. multiperiod optimization

52
How do we know the returns and the covariances?
  • In principle, from observations on the market
  • If the portfolio contains N assets, we need O(N²)
    data
  • The input data come from T observations for N
    assets
  • The estimation error is negligible as long as
    NTgtgtN², i.e. NltltT
  • In practice T is never longer than 4 years, i.e.
    T1000, whereas in a typical banking portfolio N
    is several hundreds or thousands.
  • NltltT is therefore never fulfilled in practice.

53
How do we know the returns and the covariances?
  • In principle, from observations on the market
  • If the portfolio contains N assets, we need O(N²)
    data
  • The input data come from T observations for N
    assets
  • The estimation error is negligible as long as
    NTgtgtN², i.e. NltltT
  • In practice T is never longer than 4 years, i.e.
    T1000, whereas in a typical banking portfolio N
    is several hundreds or thousands.
  • NltltT is therefore never fulfilled in practice.

54
How do we know the returns and the covariances?
  • In principle, from observations on the market
  • If the portfolio contains N assets, we need O(N²)
    data
  • The input data come from T observations for N
    assets
  • The estimation error is negligible as long as
    NTgtgtN², i.e. NltltT
  • In practice T is never longer than 4 years, i.e.
    T1000, whereas in a typical banking portfolio N
    is several hundreds or thousands.
  • NltltT is therefore never fulfilled in practice.

55
How do we know the returns and the covariances?
  • In principle, from observations on the market
  • If the portfolio contains N assets, we need O(N²)
    data
  • The input data come from T observations for N
    assets
  • The estimation error is negligible as long as
    NTgtgtN², i.e. NltltT
  • In practice T is never longer than 4 years, i.e.
    T1000, whereas in a typical banking portfolio N
    is several hundreds or thousands.
  • NltltT is therefore never fulfilled in practice.

56
How do we know the returns and the covariances?
  • In principle, from observations on the market
  • If the portfolio contains N assets, we need O(N²)
    data
  • The input data come from T observations for N
    assets
  • The estimation error is negligible as long as
    NTgtgtN², i.e. NltltT
  • In practice T is never longer than 4 years, i.e.
    T1000, whereas in a typical banking portfolio N
    is several hundreds or thousands.
  • NltltT is therefore never fulfilled in practice.

57
How do we know the returns and the covariances?
  • In principle, from observations on the market
  • If the portfolio contains N assets, we need O(N²)
    data
  • The input data come from T observations for N
    assets
  • The estimation error is negligible as long as
    NTgtgtN², i.e. NltltT
  • In practice T is never longer than 4 years, i.e.
    T1000, whereas in a typical banking portfolio N
    is several hundreds or thousands.
  • NltltT is therefore never fulfilled in practice.

58
Information deficit
  • Thus the Markowitz problem suffers from the
    curse of dimensions, or from information
    deficit
  • The estimates will contain error and the
    resulting portfolios will be suboptimal
  • How serious is this effect?
  • How sensitive are the various risk measures to
    this kind of error?
  • How can we reduce the error?

59
Information deficit
  • Thus the Markowitz problem suffers from the
    curse of dimensions, or from information
    deficit
  • The estimates will contain error and the
    resulting portfolios will be suboptimal
  • How serious is this effect?
  • How sensitive are the various risk measures to
    this kind of error?
  • How can we reduce the error?

60
Information deficit
  • Thus the Markowitz problem suffers from the
    curse of dimensions, or from information
    deficit
  • The estimates will contain error and the
    resulting portfolios will be suboptimal
  • How serious is this effect?
  • How sensitive are the various risk measures to
    this kind of error?
  • How can we reduce the error?

61
Information deficit
  • Thus the Markowitz problem suffers from the
    curse of dimensions, or from information
    deficit
  • The estimates will contain error and the
    resulting portfolios will be suboptimal
  • How serious is this effect?
  • How sensitive are the various risk measures to
    this kind of error?
  • How can we reduce the error?

62
Information deficit
  • Thus the Markowitz problem suffers from the
    curse of dimensions, or from information
    deficit
  • The estimates will contain error and the
    resulting portfolios will be suboptimal
  • How serious is this effect?
  • How sensitive are the various risk measures to
    this kind of error?
  • How can we reduce the error?

63
Fighting the curse of dimensions
  • Economists have been struggling with this problem
    for ages. Since the root of the problem is lack
    of sufficient information, the remedy is to
    inject external info into the estimate. This
    means imposing some structure on s. This
    introduces bias, but beneficial effect of noise
    reduction may compensate for this.
  • Examples
  • single-index models (ßs) All these help
    to
  • multi-index models various degrees.
  • grouping by sectors Most studies are
    based
  • principal component analysis on
    empirical data
  • Bayesian shrinkage estimators, etc.
  • Random matrix theory

64
Our approach
  • To test the noise sensitivity of various risk
    measures we use simulated data
  • The rationale behind this is that in order to be
    able to compare the sensitivity of various risk
    measures to noise, we better get rid of other
    sources of uncertainty, like non-stationarity.
    This can be achieved by using artificial data
    where we have total control over the underlying
    stochastic process.
  • For simplicity, we use iid normal variables in
    the following.

65
Our approach
  • To test the noise sensitivity of various risk
    measures we use simulated data
  • The rationale behind this is that in order to be
    able to compare the sensitivity of various risk
    measures to noise, we better get rid of other
    sources of uncertainty, like non-stationarity.
    This can be achieved by using artificial data
    where we have total control over the underlying
    stochastic process.
  • For simplicity, we use iid normal variables in
    the following.

66
Our approach
  • To test the noise sensitivity of various risk
    measures we use simulated data
  • The rationale behind this is that in order to be
    able to compare the sensitivity of various risk
    measures to noise, we better get rid of other
    sources of uncertainty, like non-stationarity.
    This can be achieved by using artificial data
    where we have total control over the underlying
    stochastic process.
  • For simplicity, we use iid normal variables in
    the following.

67
  • For such simple underlying processes the exact
    risk measure can be calculated.
  • To construct the empirical risk measure, we
    generate long time series, and cut out segments
    of length T from them, as if making observations
    on the market.
  • From these observations we construct the
    empirical risk measure and optimize our portfolio
    under it.
  • The ratio qo of the empirical and the exact risk
    measure is a measure of the estimation error due
    to noise.

68
  • For such simple underlying processes the exact
    risk measure can be calculated.
  • To construct the empirical risk measure, we
    generate long time series, and cut out segments
    of length T from them, as if making observations
    on the market.
  • From these observations we construct the
    empirical risk measure and optimize our portfolio
    under it.
  • The ratio qo of the empirical and the exact risk
    measure is a measure of the estimation error due
    to noise.

69
  • For such simple underlying processes the exact
    risk measure can be calculated.
  • To construct the empirical risk measure, we
    generate long time series, and cut out segments
    of length T from them, as if making observations
    on the market.
  • From these observations we construct the
    empirical risk measure and optimize our portfolio
    under it.
  • The ratio qo of the empirical and the exact risk
    measure is a measure of the estimation error due
    to noise.

70
  • For such simple underlying processes the exact
    risk measure can be calculated.
  • To construct the empirical risk measure, we
    generate long time series, and cut out segments
    of length T from them, as if making observations
    on the market.
  • From these observations we construct the
    empirical risk measure and optimize our portfolio
    under it.
  • The ratio qo of the empirical and the exact risk
    measure is a measure of the estimation error due
    to noise.

71
The case of variance
  • The relative error of the optimal portfolio
    is a random variable, fluctuating from sample to
    sample.
  • The weights of the optimal portfolio also
    fluctuate.

72
The distribution of qo over the samples
73
The expectation value of qo as a function of N/T
74
The critical point N /T 1
  • For a precise estimate we would need TgtgtN
  • As N approaches T, the relative error is
    increasing and diverges at the critical point
    NT.
  • The expectation value of the error can be shown
    to be
  • This innocent formula had not been noticed in the
    literature before
  • The variance of the distribution of qo diverges
    even more strongly, with an exponent -3/4.

75
Instability of the weigthsThe weights of a
portfolio of N10 iid normal variables for a
given sample, T500
76
Instability of the weigthsThe weights of a
portfolio of N100 iid normal variables for a
given sample, T500
77
The distribution of weights in a given sample
  • The optimization hardly determines the weights
    even far from the critical point!
  • The standard deviation of the weights relative to
    their exact average value also diverges at the
    critical point

78
Fluctuations of a given weight from sample to
sample, non-overlapping time-windows, N100, T500
79
Fluctuations of a given weight from sample to
sample, time-windows shifted by one step at a
time, N100, T500
80
If short selling is banned
  • If the weights are constrained to be positive,
    the instability will manifest itself by more and
    more weights becoming zero the portfolio
    spontaneously reduces its size!
  • Explanation the solution would like to run away,
    the constraints prevent it from doing so,
    therefore it will stick to the walls.
  • Similar effects are observed if we impose any
    other linear constraints, like bounds on sectors,
    etc.
  • It is clear, that in these cases the solution is
    determined more by the constraints than the
    objective function.

81
If short selling is banned
  • If the weights are constrained to be positive,
    the instability will manifest itself by more and
    more weights becoming zero the portfolio
    spontaneously reduces its size!
  • Explanation the solution would like to run away,
    the constraints prevent it from doing so,
    therefore it will stick to the walls.
  • Similar effects are observed if we impose any
    other linear constraints, like bounds on sectors,
    etc.
  • It is clear, that in these cases the solution is
    determined more by the constraints than the
    objective function.

82
If short selling is banned
  • If the weights are constrained to be positive,
    the instability will manifest itself by more and
    more weights becoming zero the portfolio
    spontaneously reduces its size!
  • Explanation the solution would like to run away,
    the constraints prevent it from doing so,
    therefore it will stick to the walls.
  • Similar effects are observed if we impose any
    other linear constraints, like bounds on sectors,
    etc.
  • It is clear, that in these cases the solution is
    determined more by the constraints than the
    objective function.

83
If short selling is banned
  • If the weights are constrained to be positive,
    the instability will manifest itself by more and
    more weights becoming zero the portfolio
    spontaneously reduces its size!
  • Explanation the solution would like to run away,
    the constraints prevent it from doing so,
    therefore it will stick to the walls.
  • Similar effects are observed if we impose any
    other linear constraints, like bounds on sectors,
    etc.
  • It is clear, that in these cases the solution is
    determined more by the constraints than the
    objective function.

84
If the variables are not iid
  • Experimenting with various market models
    (one-factor, market plus sectors, positive and
    negative covariances, etc.) shows that the main
    conclusion does not change.
  • Overwhelmingly positive correlations tend to
    enhance the instability, negative ones decrease
    it, but they do not change the power of the
    divergence, only its prefactor

85
If the variables are not iid
  • Experimenting with various market models
    (one-factor, market plus sectors, positive and
    negative covariances, etc.) shows that the main
    conclusion does not change.
  • Overwhelmingly positive correlations tend to
    enhance the instability, negative ones decrease
    it, but they do not change the power of the
    divergence, only its prefactor

86
All is not lost after filtering the noise is
much reduced, and we can even penetrate into the
region below the critical point TltN
87
Similar studies under mean absolute deviation,
expected shortfall and maximal loss
  • Lead to similar conclusions, except that the
    effect of estimation error is even more serious
  • In addition, no convincing filtering methods
    exist for these measures
  • In the case of coherent measures the existence of
    a solution becomes a probabilistic issue,
    depending on the sample
  • Calculation of this probability leads to some
    intriguing problems in random geometry

88
Similar studies under mean absolute deviation,
expected shortfall and maximal loss
  • Lead to similar conclusions, except that the
    effect of estimation error is even more serious
  • In addition, no convincing filtering methods
    exist for these measures
  • In the case of coherent measures the existence of
    a solution becomes a probabilistic issue,
    depending on the sample
  • Calculation of this probability leads to some
    intriguing problems in random geometry

89
Similar studies under mean absolute deviation,
expected shortfall and maximal loss
  • Lead to similar conclusions, except that the
    effect of estimation error is even more serious
  • In addition, no convincing filtering methods
    exist for these measures
  • In the case of coherent measures the existence of
    a solution becomes a probabilistic issue,
    depending on the sample
  • Calculation of this probability leads to some
    intriguing problems in random geometry

90
Similar studies under mean absolute deviation,
expected shortfall and maximal loss
  • Lead to similar conclusions, except that the
    effect of estimation error is even more serious
  • In addition, no convincing filtering methods
    exist for these measures
  • In the case of coherent measures the existence of
    a solution becomes a probabilistic issue,
    depending on the sample
  • Calculation of this probability leads to some
    intriguing problems in random geometry

91
Probability of finding a solution for the minimax
problem
92
(No Transcript)
93
(No Transcript)
94
(No Transcript)
95
Feasibility of optimization under ES
Probability of the existence of an optimum under
CVaR. F is the standard normal distribution. Note
the scaling in N/vT.
96
For ES the critical value of N/T depends on the
threshold ß
97
With increasing N, T ( N/T fixed) the transition
becomes sharper and sharper
98
until in the limit N, T ?8 with N/T fixed we
get a phase boundary
99
The mean relative error in portfolios optimized
under various risk measures blows up as we
approach the phase boundary
100
Distributions of qo for various risk measures
101
Instability of portfolio weights
  • Similar trends can be observed if we look into
    the weights of the optimal portfolio the weights
    display a high degree of instability already for
    variance optimized portfolios, but this
    instability is even stronger for mean absolute
    deviation, expected shortfall, and maximal loss.

102
Instability of weights for various risk measures,
non-overlapping windows
103
Instability of weights for various risk measures,
overlapping weights
104
A wider context
  • Hard computational problems (combinatorial
    optimization, random assignment, graph
    partitioning, satisfiability) the length of the
    algorithm grows exponentially with the size of
    the problem. These are practically untractable.
  • Their difficulty may depend on some internal
    parameter (e.g. the density of constraints in a
    satisfiability problem)
  • Recently it has been observed that the difficulty
    does not change gradually with the variations of
    this parameter, but there is a critical value
    where the problem becomes hard abruptly
  • This critical point is preceded by a number of
    critical phenomena

105
A wider context
  • Hard computational problems (combinatorial
    optimization, random assignment, graph
    partitioning, and satisfiability problems ) the
    length of the algorithm grows exponentially with
    the size of the problem. These are practically
    untractable.
  • Their difficulty may depend on some internal
    parameter (e.g. the density of constraints in a
    satisfiability problem)
  • Recently it has been observed that the difficulty
    does not change gradually with the variations of
    this parameter, but there is a critical value
    where the problem becomes hard abruptly
  • This critical point is preceded by a number of
    critical phenomena

106
A wider context
  • Hard computational problems (combinatorial
    optimization, random assignment, graph
    partitioning, and satisfiability problems ) the
    length of the algorithm grows exponentially with
    the size of the problem. These are practically
    untractable.
  • Their difficulty may depend on some internal
    parameter (e.g. the density of constraints in a
    satisfiability problem)
  • Recently it has been observed that the difficulty
    does not change gradually with the variations of
    this parameter, but there is a critical value
    where the problem becomes hard abruptly
  • This critical point is preceded by a number of
    critical phenomena

107
A wider context
  • Hard computational problems (combinatorial
    optimization, random assignment, graph
    partitioning, and satisfiability problems ) the
    length of the algorithm grows exponentially with
    the size of the problem. These are practically
    untractable.
  • Their difficulty may depend on some internal
    parameter (e.g. the density of constraints in a
    satisfiability problem)
  • Recently it has been observed that the difficulty
    does not change gradually with the variations of
    this parameter, but there is a critical value
    where the problem becomes hard abruptly
  • This critical point is preceded by a number of
    critical phenomena

108
  • The critical phenomena we observe in portfolio
    selection are analogous to these, they represent
    a new random Gaussian universality class within
    this family, where a number of modes go soft in
    rapid succession, as one approaches the critical
    point.
  • Filtering corresponds to discarding these soft
    modes.

109
  • The critical phenomena we observe in portfolio
    selection are analogous to these, they represent
    a new random Gaussian universality class within
    this family, where a number of modes go soft in
    rapid succesion, as one approaches the critical
    point.
  • Filtering corresponds to discarding these soft
    modes.

110
Similar examples from everyday life, and
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com