Chapter 3: Cost and Benefit Analysis

1 / 47
About This Presentation
Title:

Chapter 3: Cost and Benefit Analysis

Description:

The Surgeon General of the US. Vice Admiral Richard H. Carmona was sworn in as the 17th. Surgeon General of the United States Public Health Service ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:94
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 48
Provided by: tomob3

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Chapter 3: Cost and Benefit Analysis


1
Chapter 3 Cost and Benefit Analysis
2
Cost Identification Analysis
  • Cost Identification Analysis measures the total
    economic cost of a given medical condition or
    type of adverse health behavior.
  • Examples Cost of asthma or Alzheimers disease.
    Cost of cigarette smoking or excessive alcohol
    consumption.

3
Three Types of Costs
  • Direct medical costs all costs incurred by
    medical care providers when treating the
    condition.
  • Direct nonmedical costs monetary costs imposed
    on any nonmedical care personnel, including
    patients and their relatives.
  • Indirect costs opportunity cost of the time
    influenced by the illness or health behavior such
    as lost productivity because of sickness, injury,
    or loss of life.

4
Examples of Cost Identification Analysis
  • Fanslow et al. (1997) Social Science and Medicine
  • Cost of Homicides in New Zealand
  • Total cost slightly more than 53 million in
    1992
  • Total cost for homicide victims 24 million
    (direct medical 800,000 and indirect costs
    23 million).
  • Total cost for perpetrators almost 30 million
    (24 million direct medical costs and 6 million
    indirect costs).

5
Example - continued
  • Weiss, Gergen, and Hodgson (1992), New England
    Journal of Medicine
  • Total annual cost of asthma in the U.S. gt 6.2
    million in 1990
  • Direct medical costs gt 3.6 million
  • Indirect costs gt 2.5 million
  • Lost school days 900 million
  • Lost work due to illness 800 million
  • Lost work because of worker death 800 million

6
Value of Cost Identification Analysis
  • While valuable because it sheds light on the
    economic impact of illnesses and adverse health
    behaviors, cost identification analysis does not
    provide information on the wastefulness of
    various medical interventions or the best or
    efficient way of saving lives.
  • Cost-Benefit Analysis and Cost-Effectiveness
    Analysis do offer this type of information.

7
(No Transcript)
8
Cost-Benefit Analysis
  • The Theory of Cost-Benefit Analysis
  • Suppose an all-knowing and benevolent
    Surgeon-General (SG) is responsible for
    maximizing the social utility or happiness of the
    population in an area.
  • The SG achieves the objective by maximizing the
    total net social benefit received from each and
    every good in society.

9
The Surgeon General of the US
Vice Admiral Richard H. Carmona was sworn in as
the 17th Surgeon General of the United States
Public Health Service on August 5, 2002, and
assumed the role of Acting Assistant Secretary
for Health on February 9, 2003.
10
Theory of Cost-Benefit Analysis - continued
  • For medical services, the SG faces the following
    objective
  • Max TNSB(Q) TSB(Q) TSC(Q)
  • Where Q identifies the decision variable- how
    many medical services to produce and TSB and
    TSC reflect the total social benefit and total
    social cost associated with consuming and
    producing medical services, respectively. Total
    net social benefit (TNSB) represents the
    difference between the two.

11
TSB and TSC
  • Total social benefit can be treated as the money
    value of the satisfaction generated from
    consuming different amounts of medical services.
    TSB increases at a decreasing rate reflecting the
    law of diminishing marginal utility.
  • Total social cost can be looked at as the money
    value of all the resources used in the producing
    the different amount of medical services. TSB
    increasing at an increasing rate indicating the
    law of diminishing marginal productivity.

12
Determination of the Efficient Level
of Medical Services

TSC
TSB
A
B
Quantity of Medical Services Q
Q0
Q0 represents the efficient level of medical
services because TNSB, the vertical difference
between TCB and TSC, is the greatest.
13
MSB and MSC
  • Marginal social benefit
  • (MSB) ?TSB/?Q or slope of TSB curve
  • Marginal social cost
  • (MSC) ?TSC/?Q or slope of TSC curve
  • Geometric principle the distance between two
    curves is maximized when slopes are equal.

14
A Marginal Perspective of the Efficient Level

MSC
A
G
E
C
F
H
MSB
B
Q0
QL
QR
Quantity of Medical Services
Q
The amount of medical services at Q0 is efficient
because MSB MSC. QL reflects underprovision beca
use MSB gt MSC and QR indicates overprovision
because MSC gt MSB. Triangular areas ECF and GCH
reflect the deadweight losses associated with
inefficient outcomes.
15
The Net Benefit Calculus - revisited
  • The SGs task can be restated as setting the net
    marginal social benefit (NMSB) of each and every
    good equal to zero, or
  • NMSB(Q) MSB(Q) MSC(Q) 0
  • If NMSB(Q) gt 0 produce more.
  • If NMSB(Q) lt 0 produce less

16
Practical Side of C/B Analysis
  • Several steps must be taken to implement C/B
    analysis in practice.
  • Enumerate and quantify the benefits of the
    program or intervention, e.g.,
  • Medical costs diverted because an illness is
    prevented
  • Monetary value of any gains in productivity
    because death is postponed or illnesses prevented
  • The monetary value associated with the utility of
    being in a state of good health

17
C/B in practice - continued
  • Costs must be enumerated and quantified, e.g.,
  • Opportunity cost of each and every resource
    involved in the program or intervention.
  • Should capture both the money (explicit) and time
    (implicit) cost of resources.

18
Discounting Costs and Benefits
  • Discounting considers the time value of goods and
    services. In general, people prefer receiving
    goods and services today than in the future.
  • Stated in financial terms, a dollar received
    today is worth more than a dollar received
    tomorrow.

19
Discounting Costs and Benefits - continued
  • Since a medical intervention typically yields a
    stream of future benefits and costs, discounting
    of values is necessary to state all values in
    present day terms for comparability. For example,
    the present value of 1 received at the end of
    the year when the discount rate is 5 is
  • PV 1/(1.05) .95

20
Discounting Costs and Benefits - continued
  • In general, if there are N periods for which the
    medical intervention generates benefits and/or
    cost and the discount rate is represented by r,
    we can write
  • PV B1-C1 B2-C2 . . . BN-CN
  • (1r)1 (1r)2 (1r)N
  • N
  • Or PV ? Bi-Ci
  • i (1r)i

21
Discounting Costs and Benefits - continued
  • Careful consideration must be given to the choice
    of the discount rate. The discount rate should
    reflect societys time preference for goods and
    services.
  • If the chosen rate is higher than the true rate,
    short-term interventions will be chosen over
    long-term interventions.
  • The T-bill rate is often used and studies
    normally examine the sensitivity of the results
    to different discount rates.

22
The Value of a Human Life
  • To properly estimate the benefits of a medical
    intervention, it is often necessary to put a
    value on a human life. Two approaches.
  • Human Capital Approach equate the value of a
    persons life to the market value, in present
    value terms, of the output produced by an
    individual over the remaining years of that
    persons life.
  • For example, suppose a life-saving treatment, if
    implemented today, provides an estimated 2
    additional years of life for an estimated 10,000
    adult males, each with his human capital worth
    1,500 for those 2 years. The benefit, in terms
    of the value of life years saved, would be 15
    million.

23
Human Capital Approach - continued
  • Although widely accepted and used, human capital
    values may be understated because of gender and
    racial discrimination in the labor market.
  • Additionally, the human capital approach would
    assign a zero value of life for someone who is
    chronically unemployed.

24
Willingness to Pay Approach
  • Willingness to pay approach assigns a value of
    life based upon someones willingness to pay for
    a small reduction in the probability of dying.
  • This kind of information is revealed when people
    purchase safety equipment or are compensated for
    working in risky environments, for example.

25
Willingness to Pay Approach - continued
  • To understand the logic, consider a person who is
    deciding to purchase a device that can reduce the
    probability of dying by Pr. Using the
    cost-benefit principle, the person with a value
    of life equal to V would be indifferent about
    buying the device of cost, C, if
  • Pr V C (or marginal benefit equals marginal
    cost.)

26
Willingness to Pay - continued
  • Rewriting
  • V C/Pr
  • Thus, if society is willing to pay 100 per
    person per year for some device that improves
    environmental quality by reducing the probability
    of dying by 1 in 10,000, the imputed value of a
    life equals at least 1 million (100 divided by
    1/10,000

27
Willingness to Pay Approach - continued
  • For figures based on various types of regulations
    see Table 7-2 in text.
  • Viscusi (1993) JEL found willingness to pay
    estimates to range between 3 million and
    7million in 1990 based on labor market studies
    where workers must be compensated for undertaking
    risky jobs. Note the figure for wage premiums for
    dangerous factory jobs in Table 7-2.
  • Viscusi and others point out the willingness to
    pay numbers greatly exceed human capital
    estimates by a sizeable margin.

28
Willingness to Pay Approach - continued
  • Advantage measures the total value of life,
    both job market value and leisure time..
  • Disadvantage difficult to develop precise,
    reliable data about how much people value safety.

29
The Game of Life
  • Bon Chance!

30
Determining the Value of Your Life
  • We begin with a pool of 10,000 people.
  • Each person is asked to play a game, if willing.
  • Each person must determine the fee that he or she
    will accept or be paid to participate in the
    game.
  • The fee is based on each persons own values and
    the expected level of competition.
  • One thousand of the 10,000 lucky people with the
    lowest fees will be chosen to play the game. The
    assumption is that competition among the 1,000
    individuals will keep fees close to actual
    willingness to play the game.

31
Determining the Value of Your Life
  • One of the 1,000 players will be selected at
    random and executed.
  • The rest will receive their fees and are allowed
    to withdraw from the game.
  • How much will you charge to play the game?

32
Calculations
  • Fee probability of dying times value of life
    (i.e., MB MC)
  • Value of life Fee/probability of dying
  • Value of Life 1000 X Fee
  • Major Point The value of our lives is revealed
    by our acceptance or avoidance of risk.

33
End of Game
  • I hope you won!

34
Reconciling the Human Capital and Willingness to
Pay Approaches
  • Keeler (2001) JHE
  • Points out that standard economic models of labor
    supply assume that the value of leisure time at
    the margin is equal to the marginal wage rate
    (i.e., marginal cost equals marginal benefit of
    working).
  • If we assume the value of all time is equal to
    the wage rate (no diminishing returns due to
    leisure if so a lower bound estimate), we can
    calculate the value of life by multiplying the
    wage rate by total discounted hours of life time
    remaining.

35
Reconciliation - continued
  • Makes these assumptions
  • Workers stay employed for 5 years after we first
    observe them working.
  • After the initial period they revert to the 1990
    participation rates 92 of 25-54 year old mean
    remain employed 70 of men 55-64 16 of men 65
    and over 75 of 25-54 year old women 46 of
    women 55-64 9 of women 65 and older.
  • Hour wage rate given by the 1990 median weekly
    earnings for full-time wage and salary workers in
    their age-sex category divided by 40.
  • Workers work 2000 hours per week, if employed.
  • Workers live up to age 40 and then follow average
    US 1992 mortality rates.
  • Discount rate is 3.

36
Value of life based on value of work and leisure
time
Keeler, 2001, JHE
37
Reconciliation - continued
  • Keeler concludes by writing (p. 142)
  • Neither the estimates of value of life in the
    literature nor these estimates of value of
    lifetime remaining are very precise, but it is
    amusing that they are so close to each other.
    Maybe people really do make these calculations
    implicitly in choosing a job, or answering a
    survey.

38
C/B Analysis some applications
  • See page 191 in text and surrounding discussion
    concerning Vaccination of College Students
    against Meningococcal Disease.
  • Cutler and McClellan (2001) Health Affairs, Is
    Technological Change in Medicine Worth It?

39
Cutler and McClellan
  • Point out that most agree that technological
    change has accounted for the bulk of medical care
    cost increases over time. But do the benefits
    outweigh the added costs?
  • Also point out that the average newborn could
    expect to spend 8,000 in present value terms on
    medical care over his or her lifetime. An infant
    born in 1990 had a life expectancy that was 7
    years greater than one born in 1950 and lower
    disability but faced costs of 45,000 on medical
    care during his or her lifetime. Do the benefits
    outweigh the costs?

40
Cutler and McClellan
  • Cutler and McClellan focus on the costs and
    benefits of medical technology improvements at
    the disease level to get more precise estimates.
    Focus on
  • Heart Attacks
  • Low-birthweight infants
  • Depression
  • Cataracts
  • Breast Cancer

41
Cutler and McClellan
  • Authors point out that new technologies have a
    treatment substitution effect and a treatment
    expansion effect.
  • Authors assume a 3 discount rate and the value
    of a year of life in the absence of disease at
    100,000.

42
(No Transcript)
43
Cutler and McClellan - continued
  • Authors conclude
  • The benefits from lower infant mortality and
    better treatment of heart attacks have been
    sufficiently great that they alone are about
    equal to the rise in medical care costs over
    time. Recognizing other benefits, medical
    spending is clearly worth the costs.
  • Quality adjusted medical prices may actually have
    declined over time in contrast to standard
    figures showing rising prices for medical
    services.

44
Cost Effectiveness Analysis
  • Instead of measuring if various medical
    intervention are wasteful or not, CEA seeks to
    answer the question What is the least cost way
    of achieving a given objective?
  • Objective may be number of life years saved or
    reduced cholesterol levels or blood pressure, for
    example.

45
CEA Analysis - continued
  • Cost of a life year saved
  • Cost of Intervention
  • Number of life years saved
  • Costs would include both direct medical costs and
    direct nonmedical costs. The number of life years
    saved may also be multiplied by a quality of life
    index ranging from zero (death) to one (perfect
    health) to measure quality-adjusted live years
    saved.

46
  • Lifesaving Costs
  • Median cost of a year of life saved by various
    interventions

  • COST
  • Childhood immunizations Less than
    zero
  • Prenatal care Less than
    zero
  • Flu shots
    600
  • Water chlorination
    4,000
  • Pneumonia vaccination
    12,000
  • Breast cancer screening
    17,000
  • Construction safety rules
    38,000
  • Home radon control
    141,000
  • Asbestos controls 1.9 million
  • Radiation controls 27.4 million
  • Source Harvard Lifesaving Study

Health Prevention may be costlier than a cure
Wall Street Journal New York Jul 6, 1994
Stipp, David
47
THE END!!
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)