University of Athens Department of Economics Course: Public Finance Instructor: Vassilis T' Rapanos - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 35
About This Presentation
Title:

University of Athens Department of Economics Course: Public Finance Instructor: Vassilis T' Rapanos

Description:

... goods the costs of exclusion are extremely high (e.g. lighthouse, defence) ... goods, the pure public goods, which are not excludable, e.g. defence, lighthouse. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:81
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 36
Provided by: econ81
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: University of Athens Department of Economics Course: Public Finance Instructor: Vassilis T' Rapanos


1
University of Athens Department of Economics
Course Public Finance Instructor Vassilis T.
Rapanos Academic year 2004-2005
Outline of chapter 6 Public Goods and Publicly
Provided Private Goods
2
Public goods
  • Focus questions
  • What distinguishes public goods from private
    goods? What is a pure public good?
  • Why will private markets undersupply pure public
    goods? What is the free rider problem?
  • Why the government provides goods that are not
    pure public goods?
  • What determines the efficient supply of pure
    public goods?

3
Public goods
  • Rivalry
  • Rival if a good is used by one person, it
    cannot be used by another
  • Non-rival one persons consumption does not
    detract from or prevent another persons
    consumption (example national defence)
  • Excludability
  • If exclusion is impossible, the use of the
    price system is impossible consumers have no
    incentive to pay

4
Public goods
  • Rivalry Excludable
  • Private goods Yes Yes
  • Public goods No No
  • Pure public goods No Impossible

5
Public goods
  • It should be clear that rivalry implies that
    marginal cost is greater than zero, i.e. (MC) gt
    0. If, however, there is non-rivalry then
    marginal cost is zero, i.e. MC 0. On the other
    hand, the degree of excludability depends on the
    costs of exclusion. For non-excludable goods the
    costs of exclusion are extremely high (e.g.
    lighthouse, defence). There are, however, many
    goods which could be excludable but the cost of
    exclusion is high, (semi-excludable goods), e.g.
    TV, roads.

6
Public goods
  • .

Congested highways
Pure Private goods
MC
Impure Public goods
Rivalry ?
Pure Public goods Natioal defence, lihgthouse
Fire Protection
Easiness of exclusion ?
7
Public goods
  • The presence of public goods implies that the
    market does not lead to a Pareto efficient
    outcome for the following reason. Suppose that a
    public good brings benefits to users, i.e MBgt0.
    If there is non-rivalry then MC0. If exclusion
    is not possible then no one pays, and therefore
    no production takes place. Since MBgtMC0, and no
    production it means that there is inefficiency.
    But even if exclusion is possible, since MC0 and
    MBgt0. it means that we have under-consumption of
    this good, which is again inefficient.

8
Public goods
  • Take, for example, the case of a bridge, with
    exclusion (toll), and MC 0 (non-rivalry).

P (toll)
DDcomp
A
PA
B
C
0
Q
QM
QA
9
Public goods
  • With P 0, demand will be at Qm, which is
    efficient, but there are no revenues for the
    bridge. If PA gt 0 then quantity demanded will be
    at QA . This may cover the cost, but creates
    inefficiency (under-consumption), with an welfare
    loss equal to C. So, if there is no user fee i.e.
    there is no exclusion there will be no revenues
    and the bridge may not be built. As a result
    there will be undersupply and an efficiency loss
    equal to A C. With a user fee (exclusion) there
    will be underdemand with an efficiency loss C.
    Therefore the result is to build the bridge using
    user fee

10
Public goods
  • So
  • First best solution Build the bridge finance
    it by using lump-sum taxes.
  • Second best solution Build the bridge and
    finance it by using user fee

11
Public goods
  • Non-excludability
  • There are certain goods, the pure public goods,
    which are not excludable, e.g. defence,
    lighthouse. If the financing of these goods is
    done on a basis of voluntary contributions, then
    we shall have the free rider problem, which
    means that nobody wants to contribute.
  • The game could be a follows
  • If others pay, I dont pay.
  • If others dont pay, I dont pay.
  • So, nobody pays
  • However, in several occasions people are not as
    selfish, and there may be some who are not free
    riding

12
Public goods
  • Sum up
  • Non-rivalry implies undersupply
    (under-consumption if exclusion possible).
  • Non-excludability implies undersupply.
  • Private provision of public good inefficient!

13
Efficiency conditions for public goods.
  • As we noticed earlier, the market equilibrium in
    the case of public goods is not efficient. In the
    case of a private good we know that efficiency
    implies that
  • MRT MRS
  • With MRT equal for all producers and MRS equal
    for all consumers.

14
Efficiency conditions for public goods.
?
PPF
MRTXYMRSXY
Infifference curve
?
15
Efficiency conditions for public goods
16
Efficiency conditions for public goods
  • Suppose that we have two goods, one private good
    X and one public good G. Suppose also that there
    are two individuals, A and B. Does the condition
    for efficiency of the private goods also hold for
    public goods?
  • Not really since the same good is consumed
    jointly by both individuals. The efficiency for
    public goods is

17
Efficiency conditions for public goodsSome
mathematics
  • Suppose a society with two individuals A and B
    with utility functions respectively
  • UA UA(XA,G) and UB UB(XB,G)
  • where X is the private good and G is the public
    good with
  • XAXB X, and GAGBG
  • The income of this society is
  • Px XA Px XB PG GI
  • where Px and PG are the prices of X and G
    respectively

18
Efficiency conditions for public goodsSome
mathematics
  • Set up the Lagrangean, assuming that the utility
    of individual B remains unchanged

The first order conditions are
19
Efficiency conditions for public goodsSome
mathematics
  • With some rearrangements we get

20
Efficiency conditions for public goodsSome
mathematics
21
Demand curves for public goods
  • In the case of the demand curves for private
    goods, we ask for given price how much does each
    individual demand?
  • The demand curve for a good is the sum of the
    demand curves of all individuals. In other words
    we have a horizontal addition of individual
    demand curves.
  • In the case of the demand curves for public goods
    we at given supply of public good how much is
    each individual willing to pay for one extra unit
    public good?
  • The collective demand curve for a public good is
    the sum of amounts all individuals are willing to
    pay. So the collective demand curve is the
    vertical addition of individual demand curves

22
Efficiency conditions for public goods
23
Alternatives for determining public goods
expenditures Lindahl equilibrium
  • Collective demand curve shows at any given level
    of the public good, the sum of all individuals
    marginal willingness to pay

Supply
Lindahl equilibrium
Collective demand
24
Lindahl equilibrium
  • Lindahl equilibrium is at the intersection of
    supply curve and collective demand curve.
  • The allocation of public goods in a Lindahl
    equilibrium is Pareto efficient.
  • In order to see that let us assume that we
    produce less than the Lindahl equilibrium. Then
    the collective willingness to pay for an extra
    unit is higher than MC, which is inefficient.
    Also if we produce more the collective
    willingness to pay for an extra unit is lower
    than MC which is also inefficient. At the Lindahl
    equilibrium the collective marginal willingness
    to pay is equal to MC.

25
Lindahl equilibrium
  • The efficient provision of pure public good is at
    the point where
  • It should be made clear, however, that the
    Lindahl equilibrium is not market equilibrium,
    and that nothing ensures that the Lindahl
    equilibrium can be reached.
  • Efficiency could be ensured if each individual
    could pay his/her marginal willingness to pay,
    which means that all individuals would reveal
    their true preferences.

26
Publicly provided private goods
  • Publicly provided goods (easy to exclude) for
    which there is a large MC associated with
    supplying additional individuals are referred to
    as Publicly provided private goods. Such goods
    are education, health, nursing homes, etc.
  • If we have free provision of these goods, when MC
    gt 0, then there will be overconsumption and
    efficiency losses

27
Publicly provided private goods
P
MB D Dc
Welfare loss
MC gt 0
0
Qc Qm
28
Publicly provided private goods
  • It is clear that the size of the welfare
    (deadweight) loss depends on the shape of demand
    curve. The steeper (price inelastic) the demand
    curve the lower the welfare loss, and the flatter
    (price elastic) the demand curve the large the
    welfare loss.

29
Publicly provided private goods
  • Some times the supply of certain goods is free of
    charge because of high transaction costs or high
    exclusion costs

P
MB D Dc
Welfare loss from reduced sale
P
Welfare loss from overconsumption
Transaction costs
MC gt 0
MC
0
Qc Qm
Qe
30
Publicly provided private goods
  • Free public provision of private good is least
    inefficient if
  • Transaction costs Welfare loss from reduced sale
    gt Welfare loss from overconsumption Welfare
    loss from distortionary taxation)
  • E.g. Insurance, disability benefits, TV

31
Rationing
  • Given the inefficiencies arising from
    overconsumption when freely provided private
    goods, governments try to find ways to limit
    consumption. Any method restricting consumption
    is called a rationing system

32
Uniform provisioning
  • By uniform provisioning we offer the same
    quantity to everybody, e.g. uniform level of free
    education. We find the aggregate (average) demand
    average MB, and provide good at MC.
  • The result of uniform provisioning is that we
    avoid aggregate overconsumption, but this does
    not satisfy individual needs / demands and as a
    result we have a welfare loss if all individuals
    are not identical
  • Possible solution Offer relatively low uniform
    quantity and the possibility to buy extra
    quantities. This creates small welfare loss, for
    example, education, basic pension coverage.

33
Uniform provisioning
Averagedemand
P
High demand
Groups 2 loss from underconsumption
Low demand
Groups 2 loss from underconsumption
34
Queuing and queuing costs
  • E.g. Medical services, libraries,,

DDC
P
Welfare loss from queuing
Welfare loss from overconsumption
Demand after queuing
MCgt 0
Qc Qm
35
Queuing and queuing costs
  • Welfare loss from queuing might or might not
    be larger than welfare loss from overconsumption
    when there are no provision limit.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com